Maritime Competition under U.S. Cabotage Laws:

Regulated Bilateral Monopoly

 

 

Gary A. Lombardo

United States Merchant Marine Academy


Robert F. Mulligan

Western Carolina University

 

Abstract

 

This paper examines maritime conglomerates interacting as a regulated bilateral monopoly.  The strategic management literature on entrepreneurial innovation is reviewed.  The microeconomic theory governing two competing firms in a market closed to entry of additional competitors is developed and used to analyze competitors operating under the U.S. Cabotage Laws.  Competing firms jockey for advantage, and attempt to manoeuvre their competitive partners into disadvantageous positions.  The prisoners' dilemma framework is applied to analyze the firm’s strategic behaviour and suggest that cooperative behaviour dominates competition under certain circumstances.

 

Keywords: Cabotage laws, regulated bilateral monopoly, prisoner's dilemma, innovation, competitive advantage.

 

 

INTRODUCTION

Overseas liner shipping embodies a high fixed cost structure and extensive government regulation as well as asymmetric and, at times, seasonal demand.  Companies in this industry respond strategically in terms of shipping capacity and price decisions.  Strategic responses may be either to hold shipping capacity constant and vary price, hold price constant and vary shipping capacity, or vary both shipping capacity and price.  One rival becomes the initiator, acting first on its understanding of current and unfolding market conditions.  Other rivals respond both to the initiator and to their own understanding of market conditions.  Initiating strategic change may result in unanticipated outcomes.  The rivals' concerns that they may be disadvantaged as a result of strategic manoeuvring are at the core of conference agreements, consortia, alliances, and cabotage laws.

 

This research applies a microeconomic framework to investigate liner shipping competition and the core strategic issues of capacity and pricing within the context of protected competition under the cabotage laws.  Maritime conglomerates, like most business firms, attempt to maximize profit rather than revenue.  Thus, two issues assume paramount importance.  One, pricing to generate revenue results from the tension between sales volume and sales profitability.  Two, capacity utilization must be continually fine-tuned to provide the optimal balance between acquired resources and their profitable utilization.  Further, these two issues are dynamic in nature, whereby the maritime enterprise strives to reach the optimal equilibrium point, and then adjusts its entrepreneurial plans in response to disequilibria created by changing market conditions and the strategic behaviour of competitors.  The dynamic nature of competition and the rivals' strategic responses lead to the conceptual adoption of a strategic group of two relatively evenly matched rivals.  Rival behaviour is analysed by means of the prisoner's dilemma paradigm to guide the strategic decisions on the part of each firm with respect to shipping capacity and price decisions within the context of a nation's cabotage laws.  Cabotage laws protect the domestic rivals from foreign competition, but not from each other.  Rivals must also respond to any action initiated by the regulatory authority, which alters the contours of the market environment.

 

The strategic implications of regulated bilateral monopoly are discussed in terms of long-run and short-run incentives.  The initiating firm's strategic attempts to attain short-run advantage may be counter to its rival's interests as well as the initiator's long-run interests.  This may discourage innovation and foster a desire to establish a history of cooperative behaviour.  If this is the case, government regulation may be necessary to protect the nation's economic growth and social welfare.  The research findings are then applied to the case of two American-flagged competitors, CSX Lines and Matson, operating in the protected trade routes between Hawaii and the U.S. West Coast from 1996 to 2001.

 

The remainder of the paper is organized as follows:  a literature review is provided in "Theoretical Foundations," covering strategic groups, entrepreneurial innovation, and microeconomic theory; next the historic and behavioural background of the two firms studied is presented in "Hawaii-U.S. West Coast Trade;”  followed by a discussion of the various combinations of price and shipping capacity competition within the framework of the prisoner’s dilemma paradigm is presented and implications for strategic behaviour are discussed in "Classification of Competitive Outcomes;" leading finally to the "Conclusion."

 

THEORETICAL FOUNDATIONS

Bergantino and Veenstra (2002) conducted research to examine liner shipping competition in terms of network theory.  Additional research conducted by Panayides and Cullinane (2002) investigated competitive advantage and Fusillo (2003) examined excess capacity and entry deterrence.  Song and Panayides (2002) researched cooperative game theory and Brooks (2002) analyzed regulation in North America from a Canadian perspective.  This previous research has been helpful in understanding liner shipping competition with respect to pricing and shipping capacity.  This section surveys the relevant literature from three research streams.  The management literature on competition within strategic groups contributes a basic framework in which firms' strategic behaviours may be discussed.  The literature on innovation and entrepreneurial behaviour in business firms provides a clarifying analysis highlighting several unusual factors unique to the maritime industry.  Finally, the basic microeconomics of firm cost structure is reviewed and applied to maritime conglomerates.  

 

Strategic Group Competition

The strategic group literature can be dated from Hunt’s (1972) research on the major home appliance industry.  Porter (1980) and Barney and Hoskisson (1990) argue that strategic group mapping serves as an aid to conduct an industry structural and competitive analysis.  Peteraf and Shanely (1997) assert that strategic group analysis should be used to investigate competition of intra-industry firms.  This strategic group assessment is fundamental to understand the industry segment under investigation.  Greve (1998) and Gordon and Milne (1999) report evidence to suggest that strategic groups are comprised of organizations which are similar in terms of market position, products and the use of production technologies.  Reger and Huff (1993) argue that firms within a strategic group pursue similar strategies; which are different than the strategies of firms found in the other strategic groups within the industry.

 

For the purposes of this research project, a strategic group is formed within the liner shipping industry consisting of two relatively even matched firms.  The relevant strategic dimensions of the firms in the strategic group under study are the shipping trade lanes between the port of Honolulu, Hawaii and the ports of Long Beach/Los Angeles, Oakland, and Seattle on the West Coast of the United States; the environmental context (U.S. flagged vessels under the Cabotage Laws (Jones Act)); and the ability to compete on pricing and shipping capacity.  The size of the firms in terms of revenues, although roughly similar, is not a relevant strategic dimension.  Rivals have access to the strategic decisions of each firm by virtue of the requirement that an individual firm’s pricing becomes public information given the involvement of the U.S. Federal Maritime Commission. 

 

Each rival within the strategic group must generate its revenues from the same customer base.  Thus pricing decisions are a critical strategic dimension crucial to each firm’s success.  Correspondingly, each firm is a capital intensive enterprise that strives to balance its capacity with the level of demand for its services.  This is accomplished by either adding or removing container vessels from its fleet for the identified shipping trade lanes.  Each firm also faces asymmetrical cargo movements with the heavier shipping load being transported to Hawaii resulting in an imbalance of an increased number of empty container boxes at the Port of Honolulu than at the West Coast ports.  Certainly each rival operates in an environment where the balance of power favours the shipper, or buyer of the firm’s services.  

 

Both CSX Lines and Matson are important subsidiaries of complex corporations.  CSX Lines’ parent is a vertically integrated transportation company.  Matson’s parent is a diversified conglomerate headquartered in Honolulu with a dedicated focus to serve the Hawaii trade.  Both organizations pursue a common strategy, that of providing low-cost, integrated ocean transportation services within the United States Cabotage Laws.  As a result, they compete on a fixed trade route protected from foreign competition.  They benefit from the high entry barriers that must be overcome by potential domestic entrants who face enormous capital costs to acquire vessels, and very high human capital costs to employ individuals knowledgeable about the industry segment.  Further, the entry barriers for potential foreign entrants are virtually prohibitive as they would be required to develop a United States subsidiary to conform to the Cabotage Laws.  Conversely, CSX Lines and Matson face high exit barriers due to their ownership of high capital assets, e.g., ocean vessels and port equipment, which can neither be redeployed outside their industry segment nor sold to recover capital expenditures.  Their combined market share dwarfs that of other competitors.

Entrepreneurial Innovation

 

A maritime enterprise focuses on a delimited field of competence, most often by specializing in transport among particular destinations.  This paper examines maritime firms competing in a narrowly defined trade route between Hawaii and the U.S. West Coast.  Maritime firms may also specialize in handling certain kinds of cargo.  Piore and Sabel (1984) suggest market instability promotes competitiveness, and provides an advantage to small or highly-adaptable firms which can react more quickly in response to market volatility, high uncertainty, or rapid technological change.  Maritime enterprises certainly operate in an unstable and highly competitive environment characterized by low profit margins; however, the maritime industry has long been dominated by very large firms.  Significant barriers to entry, including high initial costs of investment, prevent small firms from competing successfully.  Thus, the maritime firms which thrive best on uncertainty are not smaller firms, but more adaptable, flexible, large firms.   This feature of the maritime industry is a significant departure from the established literature on entrepreneurial innovation.

Coase (1937) identifies transaction costs as the main reason the division of labour is organized in firms.  Transaction costs are especially critical in the highly capital-intensive maritime transport sector where firms have to live with the consequences of investment decisions over the long run, merely because the industry's capital equipment, chiefly ships and port infrastructure, are both expensive and long-lived.

 

Researchers have identified the importance of small and medium-sized firms in driving economic growth (Birch 1979, 1981, 1987; Davidsson et al 1994a, 1994b, 1996), as well as documenting negative relationships between firm growth and firm size and/or firm age (Evans 1987a, 1987b; Dunne et al 1987).  A related line of inquiry has documented decreasing shares of production and employment by large, old, well-established firms, being displaced by increasing shares to large numbers of newer, smaller firms, since about 1970 (Brock and Evans 1986, 1989; Carlsson 1989, 1992; Loveman and Sengenberger 1991; Acs 1996a; OECD 1996).  In the maritime industry, however, as suggested earlier, the more relevant distinction is between more or less adaptable large firms, than between large and small firms.

 

Small firms in most other industries act as agents of change (Acs 1992) and tend to be more innovative than large firms, which often suffer from more bureaucratic organizational structures (Acs and Audretsch 1987a, 1987b, 1988, 1993).  The level of bureaucratic inertia a firm experiences generally increases with age and size (Hannan and Freeman 1984).  Because firm age and firm size are highly correlated, empirical examinations may have difficulty separating these two as causal factors.  The established management literature on entrepreneurial innovation suggests that most entrepreneurial firms should have leaner, less bureaucratic management.

 

Large, established firms, exploiting the comparative advantage that comes from being large and established, generally deepen existing innovations the firm may have pioneered (Almeida and Kogut 1997; Almeida 1999).  Though large firms have comparative advantage in extending existing innovations they originally pioneered, eventually diminishing returns must set in.  Johansson (2001, p. 71) suggests large firms look for innovative processes, trying to improve what they already do well, whereas small firms look for innovative products, which are more important for long run growth (Acs et al 1999).  In the maritime industry, some firms may tend to innovate in terms of refining and extending processes in which they already possess comparative advantage, while more entrepreneurial firms are increasingly likely to offer innovative services and introduce cost-saving technologies.

 

As a firm grows or ages, it becomes increasingly difficult to alter the competence base of its research functions, or of the firm as a whole.  Leastadius (2000) suggests large, established firms only embrace new technology that complements the organization's existing competence base.  New technology which challenges the organization's competence base, or renders it obsolete, will typically be resisted.  Also, an established firm may be more interested in protecting existing rents than creating new profits (Geroski 1995, p. 431).  Small new firms will not have rents to protect.  Small firms' less bureaucratic organizational structure enables them to better exploit new knowledge and information, compared with large firms (Link and Reese 1990; Link and Bozeman 1991).   Since the maritime enterprises in the research project are both large, they can be classified as innovative or non-innovative based on how adaptable they prove in responding to changing market conditions and technology.  Large firms can have different degrees of bureaucracy.  A large, leanly organized maritime firm which is receptive to entrepreneurial innovation automatically has an advantage in exploiting new information and extracting competitive advantage, over a similarly large but more bureaucratic organization which attempts to avoid the challenges of innovation.

 

Empirical investigations find firm age and size have negative impacts on firm growth rates, and conversely, firm youth and smallness have positive impacts (Davidsson et al 1994a, 1994b, 1996; Liu 1999; Heshmati 2001; Johansson 2001).  The microeconomic factor of high firm turnover (firm entry combined with firm exit, which frees up resources for better uses) has been found to contribute to macroeconomic growth (Davidsson et al 1994a, 1994b, 1996; Kirchhoff 1994; Reynolds 1994, 1997, 1999; Griliches and Regev 1995; Dunne et al 1998, 1999; Foster et al 1998; Callejón and Agustí 1999; Johansson 2001).  Audretsch (1995) concludes that gross firm entry and exit are more important for generating labour employment than net firm entry.

 

Dynamic resource reallocation occurs primarily through firm entry and exit (Eliasson 1991a, 1991b; Eliasson and Taymaz 2000; Johansson 2001, p. 119).  The maritime transport industry is characterized by high turnover as firms switch markets fairly frequently.  In a highly competitive environment, such as confronts the maritime shipping industry, learnable information and knowledge are in rapid flux.  Thus maritime businesses face less incentive to acquire new information and knowledge which obsolete rapidly and afford limited benefit.  Maritime firms thus tend to retreat into established activities, lowering economic growth (Eliasson 1983, 1984, 1991b).   Overall, the maritime industry is not particularly innovative and exhibits typical behaviour of caretaking the status quo.  This may result from the industry's being closely regulated and highly subsidized.

 

Since all maritime shipping firms are viewed as large, firm age becomes a more relevant factor in distinguishing innovative from passive maritime enterprises.  In the maritime industry, a new firm is likely organized specifically to exploit a specific market opportunity.  It would be small wonder if such a firm could normally grow faster than more established firms which are comparatively immunized against innovation.   In a sense all maritime firms are also established, though they often migrate from market to market in search of better profit opportunities.  The large accumulation of wealth needed to create a shipping line presupposes a long-standing commitment to the industry, but ships being mobile assets, they tend to flow into markets where they earn the highest profits.

 

Empirical and theoretical studies of firm turnover include Orr (1974), Du Rietz (1975), Baldwin and Gorecki (1989), Acs and Audretsch (1989), and Johansson (2001).  Siegfried and Evans (1994) propose the stylized fact that entry increases and exit decreases with firm profitability and growth of local markets.  However, Audretsch (1995b) finds firm survival rates lower in highly-innovative markets than in less-innovative ones, though surviving firms have higher growth rates, an outcome also observed by Baldwin (1995).  Somewhat atypically, maritime shipping firms operate at relatively low profit margins and face high competition, but rarely go bankrupt or enter the market de novo.  More often, a diversified multinational firm will purchase a shipping component to enter the maritime industry, and sell the unit to exit.  Maritime firms, whether components of larger corporations or not, exit and enter particular markets, another uncommon feature of the maritime industry which the literature on entrepreneurial innovation largely fails to address.

 

Microeconomic Theory

This section reviews the basic economic theory relevant to understanding the competitive nature of maritime firm behaviour.  Maritime firms maximize profit rather than volume.  It appears most widely applicable to assume that firms face conventional u-shaped short-run marginal cost functions determined by either fleet purchase and building decisions, or alternatively, by fleet leasing decisions.  The size of the fleet a firm operates is fixed in the short run and determines the volume of shipping at which marginal cost (cost per additional TEU) will be minimized.  Firms attempt to match fleet size with expected demand to ensure they generally operate at or near the minimum of their short-run marginal cost curve, but because future demand is never perfectly known in advance, to a greater or lesser extent, firms generally operate out of cost-minimizing equilibrium.  Firms always desire and plan for a certain level of excess capacity, affording the opportunity to profit from unplanned (and usually temporary) increases in demand.  Without excess capacity, firms forego profit opportunities afforded by exceptional demand.  However, it is a well-known feature of maritime business planning that excess capacity is kept very low due to low profit margins.  When firm capacity greatly exceeds current demand beyond the need for excess capacity, firms have to assess whether the shortfall in demand is temporary or permanent.  In response to a demand shortfall that is expected to be permanent, firms could either cancel or reduce planned shipbuilding or ship purchase programmes, and lease out part of their current fleet to other firms.   Because firms can lease their ships to other firms, they generally have a revenue-generating alternative to maintaining significant unused excess capacity.  In addition, because a firm can generally lease additional ships, the need for excess capacity is minimized.  Thus, for simplicity, we assume zero excess capacity.

<<Figure 1 about here.>>

Figure 1 illustrates the cost structure of a typical maritime firm.   A similar approach is presented by Haralambides (2001) to describe pricing of port services.  Short-run marginal cost curves are based on resource constraints which are binding in the short run but not in the long run.  Fleet size is one example of such a constraint.  In the short run the firm is constrained by the size of its current fleet, but in the long run it can adjust fleet size to any desired level, through sales, leases, or building new ships. 

 

Firms should always operate in the region of output where short-run marginal cost is upward-sloping, represented by the dotted lines in the figure.  In the long run, average cost may be increasing, decreasing, or flat.  However, long-run average cost, even if it is decreasing, never does so rapidly enough to offset the steeper increase in short-run marginal costs.  Marginal cost necessarily rises faster in the short run than in the long run because the distinction between long-run and short-run costs is based on flexibility and reallocation of resources.  Some resources are held fixed in the short run, guaranteeing that short-run marginal costs rise faster than long-run marginal costs, which result from fewer constraints.  Constraints which may be binding in the short run include fixed-term ship-leasing and labour contracts.  Because these are periodically renegotiated, they are always less binding over the long run.  The long-run average-cost curve is depicted as downward-sloping because with significantly greater volume the firm can benefit from scale economies, and because, over the long run technology improves lowering costs. 

 


HAWAII-WEST COAST TRADE

Two maritime business competitors have been identified for the current study:  CSX Lines, a subsidiary of CSX Corporation, and Matson, a subsidiary of Alexander & Baldwin.  These two firms have a history of competing in the Hawaii/U.S. West Coast trade routes regulated under the U.S. Cabotage Laws. 

 

CSX History1

CSX Lines can be traced to its genesis, the announcement by CSX Corporation on April 21, 1986 to acquire Sea-Land approved by the U.S. Interstate Commerce Commission.  CSX Lines (as Sea-Land Service, Inc.) entered the Hawaii and Guam trades in 1987 with the goal to provide the most reliable and cost-effective containerized ocean shipping.   CSX Lines offered eight linehaul vessels in the Hawaii/Guam service.  The company offered multiple weekly sailings from the U.S. Mainland to Honolulu, Hawaii with continuing regularly scheduled barge service to the five Neighbour Islands.

During 1996, the U.S. domestic market experienced rate weakness and high fuel costs, but the firm realized record results and market share increases in each major trade lane.  Fifteen vessels were enrolled in a U.S. program for which $2.1 million a year for each participating vessel was expected to be received.  Projections called for improvement in the container-shipping industry with further consolidations and U.S. government deregulation while anticipating over-capacity to peak in 1997.  However, excess capacity and significant rate deterioration persisted through 1997.  Continued consolidation and increased government deregulation were forecast. 

 

A major reorganization took place at Sea-Land during March 16, 1999 as the subsidiary was reformed into three business units; global container shipping, international terminal operations, and domestic trade under the U.S. Cabotage Law.  A few months later, on July 22, agreement was reached with A.P. Moller-Maersk Line to purchase the international liner business of Sea-Land.  The transaction was completed on December 10, 1999.

<<Table 1 about here.>>

During the period 1996 to 2001, as viewed in Table 1, CSX Lines performance deteriorated and contributed a declining share of operating income to the CSX Corporation.  This resulted in a sizable loss by CSX Lines in 1999, which was only halted by the sale of the international component of Sea-Land.  Notably, before the sale, CSX Lines' expenses accounted for approximately 40-50% of CSX Corporation’s expenses compared to only approximately a 35-40% contribution to revenues.   After the sale CSX Lines' expenses accounted for approximately 9% of CSX Corporation's revenues as opposed to approximately 8% of revenues.

 

Matson History2

Matson is a wholly-owned subsidiary of Alexander & Baldwin, Inc.  Matson enjoys a longer history in the maritime sector than does CSX Lines.   Matson's 1996-2000 financial performance is given in Table 2.   Matson traces its origins to 1882, when Captain William Matson sailed his three-masted schooner Emma Claudina from San Francisco to Hilo, Hawaii, carrying 300 tons of food, plantation supplies, and general merchandise.  Matson has maintained its primary interest, as its fleet expanded, to carry freight between the Pacific Coast and Hawaii.

Among its many innovations and technological advancements, Matson launched its freight containerization program, which revolutionized Pacific cargo carrying during the mid to late 1950s.  Matson, continually striving for efficiency and customer service, expanded its fleet during the 1980s and early 1990s with container and ro-ro vessels.  In February 1996, Matson and American President Lines (APL) inaugurated a 10-year alliance agreement which allowed both carriers to serve their respective markets in a cost-effective manner.  For Matson, this involved the domestic trade of Guam and Micronesia and for APL, international ports in the Far East.

<<Table 2 about here.>>

Matson is the parent company of Matson Intermodal Systems, Inc. which was established in 1987.  Matson Intermodal is an intermodal marketing company that arranges North American rail and truck transportation for shippers and carriers, frequently in conjunction with ocean transportation.  Matson Logistics Solutions, Inc. was formed in 1998 to provide supply and distribution services to Matson customers, including management of transportation purchases, inventory and on-time deliveries. This subsidiary also handles special projects, including moves for unusual cargo, construction projects and film production units.  Another Matson subsidiary, Matson Terminals, Inc., established in 1921, provides container stevedoring, terminal and equipment maintenance services for Matson and other carriers in Honolulu.  Stevedoring Services of America Terminals (SSAT), which is partly owned by Matson, manages the company's container stevedoring and terminal services in the West Coast ports of Los Angeles, Oakland and Seattle.  The remaining subsidiary, Matson Services Company, Inc., established in 1969, provides harbour tugboat assistance for vessels in Kahului, Maui and Hilo, Hawaii.

 

CLASSIFICATION OF COMPETITIVE OUTCOMES

The Prisoner's Dilemma

Given the analysis of a strategic group of two rivals, the prisoner’s dilemma conceptual paradigm can be used to explain the firms’ strategic decision making with respect to pricing and shipping capacity factors.  Black (1990) provides an insightful presentation of the prisoner’s dilemma paradigm.  The prisoner’s dilemma is readily associated with the decisions of two suspects who allegedly collaborated to commit a crime and are being held in separate physical areas unable to communicate with each other while being interrogated by the police.  Each suspect cannot rely on his collaborator’s assistance to have the charges dropped.  In the classical case, a suspect’s options are to either to confess or remain silent.  If one suspect confesses and his collaborator does not, the confessor turns state’s evidence and aids in the conviction and relatively long jail sentence of his collaborator.  If both suspects confess they each receive a relatively short jail sentence.  If both suspects do not confess they may receive a very light jail sentence for a related offense or, possibly, no jail sentence at all.

 

In the context of two firms competing within a strategic group, the prisoner’s dilemma takes on a strategic competition orientation.  Instead of achieving the objective of limited or no jail time, the firms strive to increase profitability.  Overall consumer demand for consumers' goods is relatively inelastic in any highly affluent market where shipping costs are held to a very low percentage of the final retail cost to the consumer.  If overall customer demand and individual firm expenses are constant, one firm’s increase in prices will drive its customers to its competitor, resulting in the competitor’s increased profitability – increased sales volume at constant expenses.  Alternatively, if both firms raise their prices, and hold costs constant, their profit margins will increase. 

 

If one firm raises its shipping capacity to meet increased industry sector demand, it will generate additional revenues while the competitor, offering constant shipping capacity, must turn away new business.  However, if both firms each increase shipping capacity to meet increased industry sector demand the resultant overcapacity will be detrimental to their efforts to increase profitability, as their cost structure will be higher.

 

Just as it is apparent that the two suspects will need to present a united front to the interrogating police to receive the maximum benefit, so also should the two rivals within the strategic group act consistently to attain their strategic objectives.  However, given the regulatory environment in the United States and the specific requirements of the antitrust laws, the rivals are not permitted to cooperate.  Thus, their strategic decisions related to price and shipping capacity must be made in a self-interested way devoid of the rival’s cooperation.  In effect, this research will use the prisoner’s dilemma conceptual paradigm to frame the initiating decision on the part of one rival, the responding decision on the part of the second rival, and the resultant impact on both rivals.

 

Price Competition with Fixed Capacity

First we consider the case of price competition where capacity is held fixed.  For convenience the market leader, the firm which initiates each round of change, is called firm A.  Once firm A has chosen a strategy, firm B is free to respond.  We examine only qualitative changes in price, assuming fixed capacity.  There are a variety of reasons why capacity might not change when price is changed.  It might be a conscious strategic decision on the part of the competing firms.  Regulatory authorities might in the past have required firms to demonstrate increases in capacity to justify past price increases.  Regulators will not look with favour on firms which later reduce capacity, if they permit such behaviour.

 

A firm can increase price, maintain price, or lower price, providing a 3 x 3 matrix of nine possible outcomes.  We assume negligible excess capacity and therefore little scope for customer substitution between the two firms.  We assume total market demand is perfectly inelastic, that is, there is a certain volume of goods which must be shipped, almost regardless of the price, and this demand is not very sensitive to the magnitude of price changes.   Because capacity is held fixed, there is no scope for transfer of freight between firms.  Whenever one firm charges less than the other with fixed capacity, it earns lower profits than its competitor.  Outcomes are summarized in Table 3.

<<Table 3 about here.>>

If A raises price, B may respond by raising, maintaining, or lowering price.  If B raises price in response, neither firm loses or gains market share, and both firms gain revenue and profits.  Although neither firm gains strategic advantage, both firms benefit.  The only loser would be the customers.  If B maintains price in response, A gains strategic advantage.  If B lowers price, A gains an even greater strategic advantage. 

 

If A maintains price, B may respond by raising, maintaining, or lowering price.  If B raises price, B gains strategic advantage because with the assumption of fixed capacity there is no scope for transfer of freight from one carrier to the other thus the firm with the higher price earns higher revenues without facing higher costs or the loss of its customers.  If B maintains price, neither gain advantage.  If B lowers price, A gains strategic advantage.

 

If A lowers price, B may respond by raising, maintaining, or lowering price.  If B raises price it would gain additional revenues while A is losing revenue due to its lower price; thus B gains strategic advantage.  If B maintains price it would maintain revenue while A is losing revenue; thus B gains strategic advantage.  If  B lowers price, both firms lose profits.

 

Competition in Shipping Capacity with Fixed Prices

Next we consider the case of capacity competition where price is held fixed.  Outcomes are presented in Table 4.  If A increases capacity, B may respond by raising, maintaining, or lowering capacity.  If B increases capacity, both firms lose profits by raising costs.  Although both firms lower minimum SRAC by increasing capacity, thus moving down the LRAC, they have both imposed the cost of carrying unused capacity, because the total freight volume in the market is limited.  If B maintains capacity, B gains strategic advantage because its costs are unchanged, but A's rise with its expanded, unused capacity.  If B lowers capacity, this forces a transfer of demand to A, which benefits from lowered unit costs and increased freight carriage. 

<<Table 4 about here.>>

If A maintains capacity and B increases capacity, A gains strategic advantage.  If B maintains capacity, neither gains advantage.  If B lowers capacity, A gains strategic advantage, because though A's profits are unchanged, B imposes higher unit costs on itself, as well as losing revenue along with volume. 

 

If A reduces capacity and B increases capacity, B gains strategic advantage due to its increased customer contracts and lower unit costs.  If B maintains capacity, B gains strategic advantage.  If B reduces capacity, both firms lose profits.

 

Competition when Both Price and Quantity are Allowed to Vary

Finally, we consider the general case where both competitors are free to change both price and capacity.  A firm is defined as the preferred or low-price carrier whenever its shipping rates are lower than those of its competitors.  This occurs whenever a firm lowers its rates if its partner maintains or raises rates or whenever the competing firm raises rates and the first firm maintains or lowers rates.  Preferred carriers always gain market share and shipping volume unless shipping capacity constraints prevent the transfer of share and volume.  Share and volume are always transferred to preferred carriers when the preferred carrier increases capacity.  However, a preferred carrier must increase capacity to gain volume.  A preferred carrier will lose volume if it reduces capacity.

 

Even in the absence of one of the two competitive partners being the low-cost or preferred shipper, any firm that increases capacity while its partner decreases capacity must gain share at the expense of the partner.   If a firm increases capacity and its competitor increases capacity, the firm can only gain share if it is the preferred or low-cost carrier, and that may result in lower profits. 

 

If a firm increases capacity and its competitor maintains capacity, it increases share if and only if it is the preferred carrier.  If neither firm is preferred, neither gains share, but the firm which increases capacity, increases excess capacity, incurring added costs, without gaining added revenue, thus losing profits, and then the other firm gains strategic advantage.  If a firm increases capacity and its competitor decreases capacity, it gains market share regardless of price changes.  When shipping volume shifts between firms because of capacity constraints, we can say volume is supply constrained.  When volume shifts due to price, we can say volume is demand constrained.

 

If a firm maintains capacity, and its partner increases capacity, there is no shift in demand or market share unless the partner becomes the preferred carrier by lowering price or if the first firm raised price.  If both firms maintain capacity, there is no shift in demand or market share unless one firm is preferred, and then the transfer is limited by the gaining firm's initial excess capacity.  If a firm maintains capacity, and its partner decreases capacity, demand and market share shift to the first firm regardless of price changes.

 

The above considerations are formalized in the following four axioms of competitive outcomes:

 

  • Axiom 1 (diagonal symmetry): When two competitive partners make matching decisions with regard to changing or maintaining price and quantity, both must gain or lose profits together, and neither firm gains strategic advantage.

 

  • Axiom 2 (off-diagonal symmetry): The firm initiating a strategic decision with regard to changing or maintaining price and quantity has no special strategic advantage, thus the same combination of price and quantity changes leads to the same strategic outcome, without regard to which firm initiated the decision.  As a result the matrix of outcomes is symmetric about the principal diagonal.

 

  • Axiom 3 (capacity constraint): A firm receives more shipping volume whenever it increases capacity and its partner decreases capacity, or when it increases capacity and is the preferred or low-cost carrier.  Conversely, a firm loses shipping volume if it lowers capacity, or if its partner is the preferred carrier, and its partner increases capacity.

 

  • Axiom 4 (decreasing LRAC):  Firms move to new short run marginal cost curves whenever they increase shipping capacity, with lower minima.  (This assumes constantly and perceptibly improving technology, though we also assume that lowering capacity raises the minimum SRAC).  Firms incur higher marginal costs whenever they have to carry unused excess capacity, which occurs whenever both firms increase capacity and the competitive partner is the preferred or low-cost carrier.

<<Table 5 about here.>>

Based on the four axioms, we can determine strategic advantage according to table 5, which can be thought of  as a tree diagram.  This schematic is constructed from the perspective of firm A, but applies equally well to firm B.  A gains strategic advantage, the final and desired outcome, by accomplishing one of the following: increasing its own profits, or decreasing B's profits.  A can increase its profits by increasing revenue, decreasing cost, or both.  A can increase revenue by increasing price, increasing volume carried, or both.  A can decrease cost only by increasing capacity, and this works only if the added capacity is fully utilized.  A gains strategic advantage as long as B loses, so A gains advantage if B's profits diminish.  This occurs if B's revenue falls, or if B's costs rise.  B's revenue falls if B lowers price, or if B loses shipping volume, or both.  B's cost rise whenever B carries substantial unused capacity, which can only occur when A draws volume from B.

<<Table 6 about here.>>

The outcomes arrived at are presented in Table 6, based on application of the four axioms.  Since each firm chooses from among nine possible actions with regard to price and capacity, the outcomes constitute a 9x9 matrix with 81 cells.  Seventeen outcomes and cells have already been determined as presented in tables 3 and 4.  One cell is common to all three tables.  In some cases both firms increase profits, thus both gain absolute advantage, though neither gains relative advantage.  In other cases there is a clear gainer of strategic advantage as one firm either receives higher profits, or the other receives lower profits, or both.  In several cases (footnote 3 in Tables 3 and 4, footnote 4 in Table 6) both firms clearly lose profits.  There are also several instances where one firm clearly gains strategic advantage over the other, in terms of imposing higher costs or drawing volume and revenue from the competitor, though both lose profits - a Pyrrhic victory.

 

Discussion

In each row of Table 6, there is at least one column in which firm B is the unambiguous gainer of strategic advantage.  Thus firm A never receives a guaranteed strategic advantage from initiating change if B selects the appropriate response.  Consequently, change should never be initiated by either firm.  It is more advantageous to wait for the other firm to initiate change, and then respond in such a way that the responding firm (here arbitrarily designated firm B) gains strategic advantage.

 

The only conceivable motive a firm could have to initiate change would be the hope of engaging in a cooperative game.  From Table 6 it is clear that there are only two outcomes where both firms benefit -- where A increases price and either maintains or lowers capacity, and where B makes exactly the same changes.  If A looks on making one of these two moves as the first stage of a cooperative game, and if -- and only if -- B responds appropriately, that is, by matching A's changes, then both firms can increase profits.  It is also clear that one of these potentially cooperative outcomes is preferable to the other -- where both firms raise price and maintain capacity.

 

Regulators must be vigilant against this kind of cooperative gaming, because firms face clear incentives to raise price without limit, as long as both firms cooperate.   Economic theory suggests that two firms competing in a regulated bilateral monopoly face incentives to collude, thus effectively acting as a single business unit.  The analysis presented here goes beyond the conventional view.  Because the regulatory authority protects the bilateral monopoly firms from competition, it seems more logical to view the regulator, together with the bilateral monopoly firms it regulates, as a single business unit.  Then it becomes apparent that the regulatory authority faces inconsistent incentives.  The regulatory mission encompasses maximizing both the consumer surplus, which implies both minimizing profits in the regulated sector and encouraging entry by new competitors, and simultaneously ensuring that competing firms remain profitable, which implies the contrasting conditions of maximizing firm profits and discouraging entry of new firms into the regulated market.

 

Implications for Strategic Behaviour

It is not entirely clear that B will cooperate with A, however.  B can choose two alternative courses which would make it gain strategic advantage.  The cost of this short-term gain, is that A will be unlikely to make future changes which B can profit from.  In the short term, B should cooperate as long as it gains profits equal to or greater than any profits it could gain by double-crossing A.  Regulators have created a competitive environment which discourages innovation in price-setting or capacity.  Thus, regulators must assume the responsibility of initiating this kind of narrowly delimited change.  There is no clear disincentive against technological innovation which lowers costs and thus must always confer competitive advantage.

 

In the context of a regulated bilateral monopoly, firms face conflicting incentives.  In the short-term, there is no incentive to innovate in terms of either price or capacity.  A firm will only innovate with long-term cooperative gains in view.  Faced with innovation, the responding firm faces a short-term incentive to choose the most favourable outcome for itself.  Long-term incentives present the possibility of cooperative behaviour.  Once firms establish a history of cooperative behaviour, the incentive is to continue the cooperation.  In this event, regulatory authorities must intervene in the public interest.

CONCLUSION

The only conceivable motive a firm could have to initiate change would be the hope of engaging in a cooperative game.  Table 6 provides a clear indication that the firm initiating a strategic action is not guaranteed a resultant competitive advantage.  It may only gain a competitive advantage if the responding firm fails to select the appropriate strategic response.  This observation confirms the substantial body of management literature suggesting that large, established firms tend to be less innovative (Hannan and Freeman, 1984; Geroski, 1995; Almeida and Kogut, 1997; Almeida, 1999; Lombardo and Mulligan, 2003).  Consequently, change should rarely be initiated by either firm.  It is more advantageous to wait for the other firm to initiate change, and then respond in such a way that the responding firm gains strategic advantage.  This condition leads to the temptation of cooperative behaviour. 

 

This research investigated price and shipping capacity competition by two firms within a strategic group.  The theoretical approach used in this research analysis can be applied to two rivals, CSX Lines and Matson, in the maritime industry sector that serves the United States domestic Hawaii/West Coast trade routes operating under the U.S. Cabotage Laws.  Analysis of strategic behaviour of cooperative monopolists reveals a strict dichotomy between their short-run and long-run incentives.   A rationale for, and philosophy supporting, government regulation was developed.  Firms function best in this context by understanding the limitations and opportunities this business environment affords.

 

ENDNOTES

 

[1]CSX Corporation Annual Reports, 1996-2001 and CSX Corporation Homepage. November 12, 2002, www.csx.com.

 

2Alexander & Baldwin Annual Reports, 1996-2001 and Matson Homepage.  November 12, 2002, www.matson.com/history.html.

 

 

REFRERENCES

 

Acs, Z (1992).  Small business economics: a global perspective. Challenge 35(6): 38-44.

 

Acs, Z (1996). Small firms and economic growth. In: Admiraal, PH (ed.), Small Business in the Modern Economy. Cambridge: Blackwell. pp 1-62. 

 

Acs, Z and Audretsch, D (1987a). Innovation in large and small firms. Economics Letters 23(1): 109-112.

 

Acs, Z and Audretsch, D (1987b). Innovation, market structure, and firm size. Review of Economics and Statistics 69(4): 567-574.

 

Acs, Z and Audretsch, D (1988). Innovation in large and small firms: an empirical analysis. American Economic Review 78(4): 678-690.

 

Acs, Z and Audretsch, D (1989). Births and firm size. Southern Economic Journal 56(2): 467-475.

 

Acs, Z and Audretsch, D (1990a). Innovation and Small Firms. Cambridge MA: MIT Press.

 

Acs, Z and Audretsch, D (1990b). The Economics of Small Firms: a European Challenge. Dordrecht: Kluwer.

 

Acs, Z and Audretsch, D (1993). Innovation and firm size: the new learning. International Journal of Technology Management, Special Publication on Small Firms and Innovation, pp 23-35.

 

Acs, Z, Randall, M, Myles, S, and Yeung, B (1997). The internationalization of small and medium-sized enterprises: a policy perspective. Small Business Economics 9(1): 7-20.

 

Almeida, P (1999). Semiconductor startups and the exploration of new technological territory. In: Acs, Z (ed.), Are Small Firms Important? Their Role and Impact. Dordrecht: Kluwer. pp 39-50.

 

Almeida, P and Kogut, B (1997). The exploration of technological diversity and geographical localization in innovation. Small Business Economics 9(1): 21-31.

 

Audretsch, D (1995). Innovation and Industry Evolution. Cambridge MA: MIT Press.

 

Baldwin, J (1995). The Dynamics of Industrial Competition: a North American Perspective. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

 

Baldwin, J and Gorecki, P (1989). Firm entry and exit in the Canadian manufacturing sector. Statistics Canada, Analytical Studies Branch, Research Paper Series no. 23.

 

Barney, JB and Hoskisson, RE (1990). Strategic groups:  untested assertions and research proposals. Managerial and Decision Economics 11(3): 198-208.

 

Bergantino, AS and Veenstra, AW (2002). Interconnection and co-ordination:  an application of network theory to liner shipping. International Journal of Maritime Economics 4: 231-248.

 

Bergström, F (1998). Essays on the Political Economy of Industrial Policy. Stockholm: Economics Research Institute.

 

Berndt, E and  Malone, T (1995). Information, technology and the productivity paradox: getting the question right. Economic Innovations and New Technology 3(3-4): 177-182.

 

Birch, D (1979). The Job Generation Process. MIT Program on Neighborhood and Regional Change. Cambridge MA: Massachusetts Institute of Technology.

 

Birch, D (1981). Who creates jobs? The Public Interest 65(1): 3-14.

 

Birch, D (1987). Job Creation in America: How our Smallest Companies Put the Most People to Work. New York: Free Press.

 

Black, M (1990). Perplexities:  Rational Choice, the Prisoner’s Dilemma, Metaphor, Poetic Ambiguity, and Other Puzzles. Ithaca NY:  Cornell University Press.

 

Brock, W and Evans, D (1986). The Economics of Small Firms. New York: Holmes & Meyer.

 

Brock, W and Evans, D (1989). Small business economics. Small Business Economics 1(1): 7-20.

 

Brooks, MR (2002). Liner Shipping Regulation in North America:  A Canadian Perspective. International Journal of Maritime Economics 4: 281-300.

 

Callejón, M and Agustí, S (1999). Business dynamics and efficiency in industries and regions: the case of Spain. Small Business Economics 13(4): 253-271.

 

Carlsson, B (1989). The evolution of manufacturing technology and its impact on industrial structure: an international study. Small Business Economics 1(1): 21-37.

 

Carlsson, B (1992). The rise of small business: causes and consequences. In: Adams, W (ed.), Singular Europe: Economy and Polity of the European Community after 1992.  Ann Arbor: University of Michigan Press. pp 145-169. 

 

Coase, R (1937). The nature of the firm. Economica 4: 386-405.

 

Davidsson, P, Lindmark, L, and Olofsson, C (1994a). Dynamiken i svenskt näringsliv. Lund: Studentlitteratur.

 

Davidsson, P, Lindmark, L, & Olofsson, C (1994b). New firm formation and regional development in Sweden. Regional Studies 28(4): 395-410.

 

Davidsson, P, Lindmark, L, & Olofsson, C (1996). Näringslivdynamik under90-talet. Stockholm: Verket för näringslivsutveckling, the Swedish Business Development Agency (NUTEK).

 

Dunne, T, Roberts, M, & Samuelsson, L (1987). Plant turnover and gross employment flows in the U.S. manufacturing sector. Journal of Labor Economics 7(1): 48-71.

 

Dunne, T, Roberts, M, & Samuelsson, L (1988). Patterns of firm entry and exit in U.S. manufacturing industries. Rand Journal of Economics 19(4): 495-515.

 

Dunne, T, Roberts, M, & Samuelsson, L (1989). The growth and failure of U.S. manufacturing plants. Quarterly Journal of Economics 104(4): 671-698.

 

Du Rietz, G (1975). Företagsetablering i Sverige under efterkrigstiden. Stockholm: Industriens Utredningsinstitut, the Research Institute of Industrial Economics (IUI).

 

Eliasson, G (1983). On the optimal rate of structural adjustment. In: Eliasson, G; Sharefkin, M; and Ysander, BC (eds.), Policy Making in a Disorderly World Economy.  IUI Conference Reports 1983:1. Stockholm: Industriens Utredningsinstitut, the Research Institute of Industrial Economics (IUI).

 

Eliasson, G (1984). Micro heterogeneity of firms and the stability of industrial growth. Journal of Economic Policy and Corporate Strategy 5(3-4): 249-274.

 

Eliasson, G (1991a). Deregulation, innovative entry and structural diversity as a source of stable and rapid economic growth. Journal of Evolutionary Economics 1(1): 49-63.

 

Eliasson, G (1991b). Modeling the experimentally organized economy: dynamics in an empirical micro-macro model of endogenous economic growth. Journal of Economic Behavior and Organization 16(1-2): 153-182.

 

Eliasson, G and Taymaz, E (2000). Institutions, entrepreneurship, economic flexibility and growth – experiments on an evolutionary micro-to-macro model. In: Cantner, U, Hanusch, H, and Klepper, S (eds.), Economic Evolution, Learning and Complexity. Heidelberg: Physica-Verlag. pp 265-286.

 

Evans, D (1987a). The relationship between firm growth, size and age: estimates for 10 manufacturing industries. Journal of Industrial Economics 35(4): 567-581.

 

Evans, D (1987b). Tests of alternative theories for firm growth. Journal of Political Economy 95(4): 657-674.

 

Foster, L; Haltiwanger, J; and Krizan, C (1998). Aggregate productivity growth: lessons from microeconomic evidence. NBER Working Paper no. 6803.

 

Fusillo, M (2003). Excess Capacity and Entry Deterrence:  The Case of Ocean Liner Shipping Markets, Maritime Economics and Logistics 5(2): 100-115.

 

Geroski, P (1995). What do we know about entry? International Journal of Industrial Organisation 13(4): 421-440.

 

Gordon, ME and Milne, GR (1999). Selecting the dimensions that define strategic groups: a novel market-driven approach. Journal of Managerial Issues. 11(2), (Summer): 213-233.

 

Greve, HR (1998). Managerial cognition and the mimetic adoption of market positions:  what you see is what you do. Strategic Management Journal. 19(10): 967-988.

 

Grilliches, Z and Regev, H (1995). Productivity and firm turnover in Israeli industry: 1979-1988. Journal of Econometrics 65(1): 175-203.

 

Hannan, M and Freeman, J (1984). Structural inertia and organizational change. American Sociological Review 49: 149-164.

 

Haralambides, HE (2002). "Competition, Excess Capacity, and the Pricing of Port Infrastructure," International Journal of Maritime Economics. 4: 323-347.

 

Heshmati, A (2001). On the growth of micro and small firms: evidence from Sweden. Small Business Economics. 17(3): 213-228.

 

Hunt, MS (1972). Competition in the Major Home Appliance Industry, 1960 – 1970. Ph.D. dissertation, Harvard University.

 

Johansson, D (2001). The Dynamics of Firm and Industry Growth: the Swedish Computing and Communications Industry. Stockholm: Royal Institute of Technology.

 

Kirchhoff, B (1994). Entrepreneurship and Dynamic Capitalism. London: Praeger.

 

Leastadius, S (2000). Biotechnology and the potential for a radical shift of technology in forest industry. Technology Analysis and Strategic Management 12(2): 193-212.

 

Link, A and Bozeman, B (1991). Innovative behavior in small-sized firms. Small Business Economics 3(3): 179-184.

 

Link, A and Rees, J (1990). Firm size, university based research and the return to R&D. Small Business Economics 2(1): 25-33.

 

Liu, JT Tsou, MW and Hammit, J (1999). Do small plants grow faster? Evidence from the Taiwan electronics industry. Economics Letters 65(1): 121-129.

 

Lombardo, GA and Mulligan, RF (2003). Resource allocation: a Hayekian paradigm for maritime conglomerates. Quarterly Journal of Austrian Economics 6(1): 3-21.

 

Loveman, G and Sengenberger, W (1991). The re-emergence of small-scale production: an international comparison. Small Business Economics 3(1): 1-37.

 

Organisation for Economic Cooperation and Development (1996). SMEs: Employment, Innovation and Growth. Paris: OECD.

 

Orr, D (1974). The determinants of entry: a study of the Canadian manufacturing industries. Review of Economics and Statistics 56(1): 58-67.

 

Panayides, PM and Cullinane, K (2002). Competitive advantage in liner shipping:  a review and research agenda. International Journal of Maritime Economics 4: 189-209.

 

Peteraf, MA and Shanely, M (1997). Getting to know you:  a theory of strategic group identity. Strategic Management Journal 18(Special Issue): 165-186.

 

Piore, M and Sabel, C (1984). The Second Industrial Divide: Possibilities for Prosperity. New York: Basic Books.

 

Porter, ME (1980). Competitive Strategy:  Techniques for Analyzing Industries and Competitors. New York: Free Press.

 

Reger, RK and Huff, AS (1993). Strategic groups:  A cognitive perspective.  Strategic Management Journal  14: 103-123.

 

Reynolds, P (1994). Autonomous firm dynamics and economic growth in the United States, 1896-1990. Regional Studies 28(4): 429-442.

 

Reynolds, P (1997). Who starts new firms? Preliminary explorations of firms-in-gestation, Small Business Economics 9(5): 449-462.

 

Reynolds, P (1999). Creative destruction: source or symptom of economic growth? In: Acs, Z Carlsson, B and Karlsson C (eds.), Entrepreneurship, Small and Medium-sized Enterprises and the Macroeconomy. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press. pp 97-135.

 

Song, DW and Panayides PM (2002). A conceptual application of cooperative game theory to liner shipping strategic alliances. Maritime Policy & Management 29(3): 285-301.


Figure 1

Maritime Long-run and Short-run Cost Structure

Text Box: Cost, Price

 


 

Table 1

CSX Lines Financial Performance1,2,3

Year

CSX Lines Operating Revenue

CSX Corp. Operating Revenue

CSX Lines as Percentage of CSX Corp.

CSX Lines Expenses

CSX Corp. Expenses

CSX Lines as Percentage  CSX Corp.

CSX Lines Operating Income

CSX Corp. Operating Income

CSX Lines as Percentage of CSX Corp.

2001

$681

$8,110

8.40%

$649

$7,153

9.07%

$32

$957

3.34%

2000

$666

$8,191

8.13%

$666

$7,386

9.02%

$0

$805

-

1999

$3,809

$10,375

36.71%

$4,020

$9,802

41.01%

$(211)

$573

-

1998

$3,916

$9,490

41.26%

$3,783

$8,359

45.26%

$133

$1,131

11.76%

1997

$3,991

$10,232

39.01%

$3,713

$8,673

42.81%

$278

$1,559

17.83%

1996

$4,051

$10,220

39.64%

$3,733

$8,715

42.83%

$318

$1, 505

21.13%

Notes:

1All monetary values stated in millions of dollars.

2Reclassification and presentation of financial data occurred at time of Sea-Land sale to Maersk on December 10, 1999.

3 Source:  Prepared by authors.


 

Table 2

Matson Financial Performance1,2

Year

Matson Operating Revenue

A & B Operating Revenue

Matson as  Percentage of A & B

Matson Expenses

A & B Expenses

Matson as  Percentage  A & B

Matson Operating Profit

A & B Operating Profit

Matson as Percentage of A & B

2001

$797

$1,190

66.97%

$735

$942

78.03%

$62

$248

25.00%

2000

$851

$1,069

79.61%

$757

$910

83.19%

$94

$159

59.12%

1999

$779

$1,000

77.90%

$695

$857

81.10%

$84

$143

58.74%

1998

$748

$1,343

55.70%

$682

$1,208

56.46%

$66

$135

48.89%

1997

$721

$1,290

55.89%

$641

$1,142

56.13%

$80

$148

54.05%

1996

$687

$1,270

54.09%

$605

$1,119

54.07%

82

$151

54.30%

Notes:

1All monetary units stated in millions of dollars.

2 Source:  Prepared by authors.

 


 

 

Table 3

Strategic Outcome Possibilities Based on Price Competition1,2,4

 

 

 

APC

 

BPC

Increase Price

Maintain Price

Decrease Price

Increase Price

AB

A

A

Maintain Price

B

X

A

Decrease Price

B

B

X3

Notes:

1Assumptions:

              1.  Shipping capacity held fixed.

              2.  No transfer of freight carriage between firms.

2Company/companies gaining strategic advantage indicated in cells.  "AB" indicates both firms benefit equally through increased profits.  "X" indicates indeterminate outcome.

3Both firms lose profits.

4Source:  Prepared by authors.

 


 

 

 

Table 4

Strategic Outcome Possibilities Based on Shipping Capacity1,2,4

 

 

 

 

 

ASC

 

BSC

Increase

Shipping Capacity

Maintain

Shipping Capacity

Decrease

Shipping Capacity

Increase

Shipping Capacity

X3

B

A

Maintain

Shipping Capacity

A

X

A

Decrease

Shipping Capacity

B

B

X3

Notes:

1Assumptions:

              1.  Prices held fixed.

              2.  No additional latent demand.

              3.  Lowering capacity raises minimum SRAC.

              4.  Raising capacity lowers minimum SRAC.

2Company/companies gaining strategic advantage indicated in cells. "X" indicates indeterminate outcome.

3Both firms lose profits.

4Source:  Prepared by authors.

 

 

 


 

Table 5

Conditions for Strategic Advantage

A gains strategic advantage

increases A’s profits

increases A’s revenue

increase A's price with fixed volume

increase A's volume with fixed price

increase both A's price and volume

decreases A’s costs

increase A's capacity and volume

lowers B's profits

decreases B's revenue

lower B's volume with fixed price

B lowers price with fixed volume

B lowers price and volume

increases B's costs

A draws volume from B

 

 

 


 

Table 6

Strategic Outcome Possibilities Based on both Price Competition and Shipping Capacity1,2,3,5

APCSC

 

BPCSC

P↑ C↑

P↑ C↔

P↑ C↓

P↔ C↑

PC

P↔C↓

P↓ C↑

P↓ C↔

P↓ C↓

 

P↑ C↑

 

X4

B

A

B

B

A

B

X4

A

 

P↑ C↔

 

A

AB

A

B

A

A

B

A

A

 

P↑ C↓

 

B

B

AB

B

A

A

B

X

A

 

P↔C↑

 

A

A

A

X4

B

A

B

X4

A

 

P↔C↔

 

A

B

B

A

X

A

B

A

A

 

P↔C↓

 

B

B

B

B

B

X4

B

X4

A

 

P↓ C↑

 

A

A

A

A

A

A

X4

B4

A

 

P↓ C↔

 

X4

B

X

X4

B

X4

A4

X4

A4

 

P↓ C↓

 

B

B

B

B

B

B

B

B4

X4

Notes:

1 ↑ signifies an increase;  ↔ signifies maintain (neither increase nor decrease); and ↓ signifies a decrease.

2Assumptions:

              1.  No additional latent demand.

              2.  Lowering capacity raises minimum SRAC.

              3.  Raising capacity lowers minimum SRAC.

3Company/companies gaining strategic advantage indicated in cells. "AB" indicates both firms benefit equally through increased profits.  "X" indicates indeterminate outcome.

4Both firms lose profits.

5Source:  Prepared by authors.