A Fractal Comparison of
Real and Austrian Business Cycle Models
Robert F. Mulligan, Ph.D.
Department of Business Computer Information
Systems & Economics
Phone: 828-227-3329
Fax: 828-227-7414
Email: mulligan@wcu.edu
Acknowledgements
Robert F. Mulligan is associate professor of economics in
the Department of Business Computer Information Systems and Economics at
Western Carolina University College of Business and a research associate of the
State University of New York at
Abstract
This
paper examines macromonetary data for fractal character and stochastic
dependence. Lo's modified R/S test for
stochastic dependence is used to explore the data's fractal properties along
with five fractal analysis techniques for estimating the Hurst exponent,
Mandelbrot-Lévy characteristic exponent, and fractal dimension. Techniques employed are rescaled-range
analysis, power-spectral density analysis, roughness-length analysis, the
variogram or structure function method, and wavelet analysis. Monthly data is analyzed over the 1959-2006
range and a quarterly dataset extending from 1947-2006 is also examined. Strong evidence is found for stochastic
dependence in the monetary aggregates, which suggests an activist monetary
policy, and for nominal consumption expenditures, supporting Austrian business
cycle theory. No evidence for stochastic
dependence in investment productivity is found, and this finding is invariant
to whether productivity ratios are adjusted to account for credit expansion.
Introduction
This paper
examines the distribution of changes in a vector of macromonetary data. Statistical tests focusing on five
alternative methods for estimating
Mandelbrot's
(1972a, 1975, 1977) and Mandelbrot and Wallis's (1969) R/S or rescaled range
analysis characterizes time series as one of four types: 1.) dependent or
autocorrelated series, 2.) persistent, trend-reinforcing series, also called
biased random walks, random walks with drift, or fractional Brownian
motion, 3.) random walks, or 4.)
anti-persistent, ergodic, or mean-reverting series. Mandelbrot-Lévy distributions are a general
class of probability distributions derived from the generalized central limit
theorem, and include the normal or Gaussian and Cauchy as limiting cases (Lévy
1925; Gnedenko and Kolmolgorov 1954).
Samuelson (1982) popularized the term Mandelbrot-Lévy. The reciprocal of the Mandelbrot-Lévy characteristic exponent α is the Hurst exponent H, and estimates
of H indicate the probability distribution underlying a time series. H = 1/α
= 1/2 for normally-distributed or Gaussian processes. H = 1 for Cauchy-distributed processes. H = 2 for the Lévy distribution governing tosses of a fair coin. H is also related to the fractal dimension D
by the relationship D = 2 - H. Series
with different fractal statistics exhibit different properties as described in
Table 1.
Table 1 Fractal Taxonomy of
Time Series |
||||
Term |
'Color' |
(H) |
Fractal dimension (D) |
Characteristic
exponent (α) |
Antipersistent, Ergodic, Mean-reverting, Negative serial correlation, 1/f noise |
Pink noise |
0 ≤ H < ½ |
0 ≤ D < 1.50 |
2.00 ≤ α
< ∞ |
Gaussian process, Normal distribution |
White noise |
H º ½ |
D º 1.50 |
α º
2.00 |
Brownian motion, Wiener process |
Brown noise |
H º ½ |
D º 1.50 |
α º
2.00 |
Persistent, Trend-reinforcing, Hurst process |
Black noise |
½ < H < 1 |
1 < D < 1.50 |
1.00 < α
< 2.00 |
Cauchy process, Cauchy distribution |
Cauchy noise |
H º 1 |
D º 1 |
α º 1 |
Note: Brown noise
or Brownian motion is the cumulative sum of a normally-distributed
white-noise process. The changes in,
or returns on, a Brownian motion, are white noise. Fractal statistics are the same for brown
and white noise because the brown-noise process is differenced as part of the
estimation process, yielding white noise. |
Literature review
The search for long memory in capital markets has been a fixture in the literature applying fractal geometry and chaos theory to economics since Mandelbrot (1963b) shifted his attention from income distribution to speculative prices. Fractal analysis has been applied extensively to equities (Green and Fielitz 1977; Lo 1991; Barkoulas and Baum 1996; Peters 1994, 1996; Koppl et al 1997; Kraemer and Runde 1997; Barkoulas and Travlos 1998; Koppl and Nardone 2001; Mulligan 2004, and Mulligan and Lombardo 2004), interest rates (Duan and Jacobs 1996; Barkoulas and Baum 1997a, 1997b; and Hays, Schreiber, et al 2000), commodities (Barkoulas, Baum, and Ogutz 1998), exchange rates (Cheung 1993; Byers and Peel 1996; Koppl and Yeager 1996; Barkoulas and Baum 1997c; Chou and Shih 1997; Andersen and Bollerslev 1997; Koppl and Broussard 1999, and Mulligan 2000a), and derivatives (Fang, Lai, and Lai 1994; Barcoulas, Labys, and Onochie 1997; and Corazza, Malliaris, and Nardelli 1997). Fractal analysis has also been applied to income distribution (Mandelbrot 1963a) and macroeconomic data (Peters 1994, 1996).
Gilanshah and Koppl (2005) advance the thesis that postwar money demand and monetary policy behavior were mostly stable from 1945-1970, but that instability emerged during the seventies as the Federal Reserve System adopted more activist policies and procedures. If the Federal Reserve System becomes an active market player at times, the influence of this one “big player” would be to reduce the stability of money demand, as the many smaller players attempt to react to, as well as anticipate, big player moves. The smaller players' behavior should exhibit herding if it is difficult to anticipate or observe big player behavior, or if that behavior changes abruptly at the big player’s discretion, and if it is relatively easy to observe behavior of other small players. If the Federal Reserve System is a big player acting in accordance with discretion as opposed to rules, the many little players would not appear to be following any coherent behavior, even if little players developed and followed consistent and rational strategic responses. Monetary aggregates would exhibit stochastic dependence over time, and this statistical behavior could spill over into other macroeconomic data processes. Even if the little players respond according to set rules, because the big player acts unpredictably through discretion, the little players’ behavior seems incoherent. If this reading is correct, the instability in money demand is not a statistical artifact of specification error, and cannot be removed by adding variables to conventional money demand models.
As the Federal Reserve System began to adopt more activist policy measures during the 1970s, estimates generated by standard money demand specifications began to show sizable prediction errors. If activist monetary policy does indeed impose instability, this implies that the Federal Reserve System should abandon discretion and pursue money supply targets according to fixed rules. This implication runs counter to a prevailing inference presented in the literature on money demand instability. Mishkin’s (1995:572) view is representative: “because the money demand function has become unstable, velocity is now harder to predict, and setting rigid money supply targets in order to control aggregate spending in the economy may not be an effective way to conduct monetary policy.” But as Gilanshah and Koppl (2005) argue, since the money demand instability results from Federal Reserve activism, the situation calls for less discretion, not more. In their view, one mechanism introducing herding or bandwagon effects in money demand is cash managers’ attempts to enhance their reputations, which enhances their job security and earning potential. Cash managers seek to enhance their reputations in a manner similar to, and for the same reasons as, portfolio managers (Scharfstein and Stein 1990). Cash managers achieve and maintain reputation through conformity with industry practice, a global criterion, and through conduct appropriate to the unique circumstances of their business enterprise, a local criterion. Pursuit of the global criterion imposes herding behavior or bandwagon effects. If cash managers act as others do and things go well, their reputation is assured. If they act as others do and things go badly, the blame is shared throughout the profession. If cash managers defy prevailing practice in their profession and things go badly, their reputation is ruined. Sharfstein and Stein (1990:466) call this incentive to imitate standard practices the “sharing-the-blame effect.” Similar behavior can be observed among the majority of less-innovative entrepreneurial planners.
If entrepreneurial planners defy the common wisdom and things go well, their reputation is strongly enhanced and they enjoy improved income prospects and job security. This is a powerful counter-incentive to herding. Not all entrepreneurial planners are constitutionally capable of acting independently of their peers, and some may require the security of the herd. Some entrepreneurs will herd; others will not. Big player conduct affects the fraction that herds. Activist monetary policy, particularly credit expansion, impairs the value of local information which could be exploited by the more independent entrepreneurs. Thus discretionary conduct by the monetary authorities promotes herding and introduces more volatility into macromonetary data.
Data
The data are monthly-observed monetary aggregates, macroeconomic expenditures, indexes, and ratios over the 1959-2006 range. Macroeconomic data, specifically output measures and interest rates, are also examined over the same period to determine if their behavior appears significantly driven by the monetary data. Quarterly macromonetary processes were examined over the 1947-2006 period. Monetary series were extended from 1947-1958 from Gordon (1986:805-806).
GMB is the logarithmic first difference of the monetary base.
GM1 is the logarithmic first difference of M1.
GM2 is the logarithmic first difference of M2.
GM3 is the logarithmic first difference of M3.
GMZM is the logarithmic first difference of MZM.
GCUR is the logarithmic first difference of currency.
GRR is the logarithmic first difference of required reserves.
GER is the logarithmic first difference of excess reserves.
GCD is the logarithmic first difference of checkable deposits.
GTD is the logarithmic first difference of time deposits.
GR10Y is the first difference of the 10 year Treasury bond rate.
GR3M is the first difference of the 3 month Treasury bill secondary market rate.
GR is the first difference of the term spread, the 10 year rate minus the 3 month rate.
GIIP is the first difference of the index of industrial production.
GCN is the logarithmic first difference of nominal consumption expenditures.
GC is the logarithmic first difference of real consumption expenditures.
GCP is the first difference of the consumption expenditures deflator.
GDI is the logarithmic first difference of real disposable income.
GIN is the logarithmic first difference of nominal investment expenditures.
GI is the logarithmic first difference of real investment expenditures.
GP is the first difference of the GDP deflator.
RP is a productivity index computed as the ratio of nominal consumption expenditures divided by nominal investment expenditures. The productivity indices are difference-stationary so are not differenced for fractal analysis.
AP1 an ABC-adjusted productivity index computed as the ratio of nominal consumption expenditures minus the increase in M1 from the last period divided by nominal investment expenditures plus the increase in M1 from the last period. As with RP, AP1 is difference-stationary.
AP2 is the first difference of a productivity index computed as above, but using M2 in place of M1.
APB is a productivity index computed as above, but using the monetary base in place of M1.
Time series which were already represented as interest rates, percentages, or ratios, were simply first differenced without taking logarithms. Productivity measures were not differenced because they were already difference-stationary.
Methodology
Long memory series exhibit non-periodic long cycles, or persistent dependence between observations far apart in time; i.e., observable patterns which tend to repeat. Long memory or persistent series tend to reverse themselves less often than a purely random series. Thus, they display a trend, and are also called black noise, in contrast to purely random white noise. Persistent series have long memory in that events are correlated over long time periods. In contrast, short-term dependent time series include standard autoregressive moving average and Markov processes, and have the property that observations far apart exhibit little or no statistical dependence. R/S or rescaled range analysis distinguishes random from non-random or deterministic series. The rescaled range is the range divided (rescaled) by the standard deviation. Seemingly random time series may be deterministic chaos, fractional Brownian motion (FBM), or a mixture of random and non-random components.
Conventional statistical techniques lack power to distinguish unpredictable random components from highly predictable deterministic components. R/S analysis evolved to address this difficulty. R/S analysis exploits the structure of dependence in time series irrespective of their marginal distributions, statistically identifying non-periodic cyclic long run dependence as distinguished from short dependence or Markov character and periodic variation (Mandelbot 1972a: 259-260). The difference between long-memory processes, also called non-periodic long cycles, and short-term dependence, is that each observation in long memory processes has a persistent effect, on average, on all subsequent observations, up to some horizon after which memory is lost, whereas in contrast, short-term dependent processes display little or no memory of the past, and what short-term dependence can be observed often diminishes with the square of the time elapsed. For equity prices, long memory can be observed when a stock follows a trend or repeats a cyclical movement, even though the cycles can have time-varying frequencies. Short-term dependence is indicated when there are no observable trends or patterns beyond a very short time span, and the impact of any outliers or extreme values diminishes rapidly over time.
Mandelbrot (1963a, 1963b) demonstrated all
stationary series can be categorized in accordance with their
Results
Many macromonetary
series are anti-persistent
or ergodic, mean-reverting, or pink noise processes
with (0.00 < H < 0.50), indicating they are more volatile than a random
walk. Pink noise processes are used to
model dynamic turbulence. Ergodic or
antipersistent processes reverse themselves more often than purely random
series. Ergodicity, that is, H
significantly below 0.50, indicate policy makers persistently over-react to new
information, imposing more macroeconomic volatility than would maintain in the
absence of policy, and never learn not to over-react. This observed phenomenon is directly
analogous to Mussa's (1984) disequilibrium overshooting, in which the market process
of adjustment toward final equilbrium is unstable, and never quiets down. Hs significantly above 0.50 demonstrate
macroeconomic data series are not random walks.
|
Table 2 Fractal Analyses of Macromonetary Monthly Data Processes 1959-2006 Estimated Hurst Exponent H, Various Methods (Standard Errors in Parentheses) |
|||||
variable |
R/S |
Power Spectrum |
Roughness-length |
Variogram |
Wavelet |
|
GMB |
0.018 |
-0.392 |
-0.044 |
0.003 |
0.514 |
|
|
(0.0194634) |
(6.2957945) |
(0.00269) |
(1.1896007) |
|
|
GM1 |
-0.013 |
-0.404 |
-0.048 |
-0.006 |
0.851 |
|
|
(0.0128657) |
(11.1950188) |
(0.0014695) |
(2.8028963) |
|
|
GM2 |
0.075 |
-0.29 |
-0.030 |
0.006 |
0.767 |
|
|
(0.0100815) |
(13.3460836) |
(0.0008523) |
(1.3703301) |
|
|
GM3 |
0.049 |
-0.1605 |
-0.034 |
0.034 |
0.597 |
|
|
(0.0171313) |
(5.5036998) |
(0.0009275) |
(0.6806059) |
|
|
GMZM |
0.176 |
-0.2285 |
0.032 |
0.040 |
0.545 |
|
|
(0.0056194) |
(5.624958) |
(0.0005663) |
(0.3498935) |
|
|
GCUR |
-0.007 |
-0.4175 |
0.014 |
-0.010 |
0.819 |
|
|
(0.0198405) |
(12.1109514) |
(0.0004026) |
(2.8371727) |
|
|
GRR |
0.098 |
-0.496 |
-0.056 |
0.001 |
0.748 |
|
|
(0.0118314) |
(6.1537476) |
(0.0012239) |
(0.5085489) |
|
|
GER |
0.079 |
-1.0185 |
-0.093 |
-0.004 |
0.985 |
|
|
(0.0106919) |
(6.4823799) |
(0.0048483) |
(0.0637986) |
|
|
GCD |
-0.012 |
-0.4115 |
-0.066 |
-0.008 |
0.872 |
|
|
(0.0132301) |
(10.5566654) |
(0.0014590) |
(2.2587965) |
|
|
GTD |
0.279 |
-0.058 |
0.078 |
0.113 |
0.192 |
|
|
(0.0040276) |
(5.5141182) |
(0.0010699) |
(0.0619385) |
|
|
GR10Y |
0.191 |
-0.4425 |
0.064 |
0.021 |
0.436 |
|
|
(0.0154230) |
(2.7973051) |
(0.0002411) |
(0.0531330) |
|
|
GR3M |
0.241 |
-0.5015 |
0.119 |
0.024 |
0.361 |
|
|
(0.0110211) |
(5.6629744) |
(0.0013522) |
(0.0937309) |
|
|
GR |
0.228 |
-0.663 |
0.083 |
0.016 |
0.553 |
|
|
(0.0055240) |
(8.0740194) |
(0.0007747) |
(0.0593133) |
|
|
GIIP |
0.215 |
-0.304 |
0.089 |
0.034 |
0.255 |
|
|
(0.0142341) |
(4.0755129) |
(0.0001330) |
(0.0258054) |
|
|
GCN |
0.110 |
-0.539 |
-0.005 |
-0.008 |
0.786 |
|
|
(0.0040738) |
(6.8441381) |
(0.0004587) |
(0.0303925) |
|
|
GC |
0.132 |
-0.5175 |
0.006 |
-0.001 |
0.755 |
|
|
(0.0044611) |
(4.0951791) |
(0.0002475) |
(0.0305760) |
|
|
GCP |
0.220 |
-0.165 |
-0.006 |
0.039 |
0.341 |
|
|
(0.0056719) |
(6.2382107) |
(0.0004521) |
(0.0955249) |
|
|
|
Note: The
Mandelbrot-Lévy characteristic exponent alpha is the reciprocal of the |
|||||
Table 3 Lo Test for Stochastic
Dependence on Macromonetary Monthly Data Processes 1959-2006 |
|||||||||||||
|
|
Autoregressive Order |
|||||||||||
|
N |
1 |
2 |
3 |
4 |
5 |
6 |
7 |
8 |
9 |
10 |
11 |
12 |
GMB |
576 |
1.62955 |
1.74704 |
1.87159 |
1.97637 |
2.02415 |
1.9856 |
1.93953 |
1.91353 |
1.91913 |
1.99047 |
2.02572 |
1.92456 |
|
|
0.09502 * |
0.05006
** |
0.02359
** |
0.01184
** |
0.00850
** |
0.01112
** |
0.01518
** |
0.01801
** |
0.01737
** |
0.01075
** |
0.00841
** |
0.01676
** |
GM1 |
575 |
1.84767 |
2.21345 |
2.2386 |
2.25967 |
2.34268 |
2.28693 |
2.30709 |
2.3193 |
2.24153 |
2.30942 |
2.41049 |
2.22362 |
|
|
0.02742
** |
0.00207*** |
0.00169*** |
0.00143*** |
0.00072*** |
0.00114*** |
0.00097*** |
0.00087*** |
0.00165*** |
0.00095*** |
0.00040*** |
0.00191*** |
GM2 |
575 |
3.08061 |
3.21314 |
2.95373 |
2.79783 |
2.72089 |
2.60229 |
2.53809 |
2.4797 |
2.38055 |
2.33232 |
2.30495 |
2.21712 |
|
|
0.00000*** |
0.00000*** |
0.00000*** |
0.00001*** |
0.00002*** |
0.00007*** |
0.00013*** |
0.00022*** |
0.00052*** |
0.00078*** |
0.00098*** |
0.00201*** |
GM3 |
565 |
3.4289 |
3.27621 |
2.97688 |
2.7754 |
2.64299 |
2.51502 |
2.42511 |
2.34378 |
2.25247 |
2.18724 |
2.13304 |
2.0593 |
|
|
0.00000*** |
0.00000*** |
0.00000*** |
0.00001*** |
0.00005*** |
0.00016*** |
0.00035*** |
0.00071*** |
0.00151*** |
0.00254*** |
0.00384*** |
0.00662
** |
GMZM |
575 |
1.82378 |
1.74877 |
1.62799 |
1.55318 |
1.51153 |
1.4679 |
1.44394 |
1.42206 |
1.38932 |
1.37295 |
1.36474 |
1.33765 |
|
|
0.03177
** |
0.04957
** |
0.09579 * |
0.13889 |
0.1687 |
0.20481 |
0.22685 |
0.24838 |
0.28309 |
0.30154 |
0.31107 |
0.34378 |
GCUR |
575 |
1.99419 |
2.18628 |
2.3859 |
2.45972 |
2.42729 |
2.43622 |
2.39082 |
2.32109 |
2.30198 |
2.37666 |
2.43066 |
2.27421 |
|
|
0.01048
** |
0.00256*** |
0.00049*** |
0.00026*** |
0.00034*** |
0.00032*** |
0.00047*** |
0.00086*** |
0.00101*** |
0.00054*** |
0.00033*** |
0.00127*** |
GRR |
576 |
1.28968 |
1.43671 |
1.43007 |
1.43589 |
1.47097 |
1.4434 |
1.45324 |
1.46212 |
1.43545 |
1.45752 |
1.48967 |
1.43397 |
|
|
0.40616 |
0.23382 |
0.24035 |
0.23462 |
0.2021 |
0.22737 |
0.21811 |
0.20999 |
0.23505 |
0.21416 |
0.18615 |
0.2365 |
GER |
576 |
0.988 |
1.15463 |
1.24377 |
1.36766 |
1.56416 |
1.62141 |
1.71392 |
1.80396 |
1.93727 |
2.09225 |
2.25272 |
2.19475 |
|
|
0.83648 |
0.60324 |
0.47046 |
0.30766 |
0.13175 |
0.09908 * |
0.06039 * |
0.03583
** |
0.01541
** |
0.00521
** |
0.00151*** |
0.00239*** |
GCD |
575 |
1.89645 |
2.28756 |
2.24288 |
2.24416 |
2.31028 |
2.24438 |
2.25419 |
2.26823 |
2.17607 |
2.20939 |
2.28661 |
2.12456 |
|
|
0.02013
** |
0.00114*** |
0.00163*** |
0.00162*** |
0.00094*** |
0.00161*** |
0.00149*** |
0.00133*** |
0.00277*** |
0.00213*** |
0.00114*** |
0.00410*** |
GTD |
565 |
4.09756 |
3.54408 |
3.18204 |
2.9273 |
2.72514 |
2.56345 |
2.4313 |
2.32089 |
2.2253 |
2.14348 |
2.07106 |
2.00318 |
|
|
0.00000*** |
0.00000*** |
0.00000*** |
0.00000*** |
0.00002*** |
0.00010*** |
0.00033*** |
0.00086*** |
0.00188*** |
0.00355*** |
0.00608
** |
0.00984
** |
GR10Y |
576 |
1.54439 |
1.52775 |
1.53391 |
1.53711 |
1.52375 |
1.51733 |
1.52429 |
1.52307 |
1.51385 |
1.49982 |
1.48114 |
1.47024 |
|
|
0.14481 |
0.15656 |
0.15213 |
0.14987 |
0.15949 |
0.16428 |
0.1591 |
0.16 |
0.16692 |
0.17789 |
0.19331 |
0.20274 |
GR3M |
576 |
1.274 |
1.24959 |
1.25874 |
1.2697 |
1.27032 |
1.29647 |
1.34068 |
1.36586 |
1.36067 |
1.34775 |
1.33903 |
1.34247 |
|
|
0.42768 |
0.4621 |
0.44908 |
0.43367 |
0.4328 |
0.39702 |
0.34002 |
0.30976 |
0.31586 |
0.33137 |
0.34208 |
0.33782 |
GR |
576 |
0.71535 |
0.71662 |
0.71911 |
0.72688 |
0.74001 |
0.76082 |
0.78301 |
0.79361 |
0.78949 |
0.7868 |
0.78948 |
0.80006 |
|
|
0.99562 |
0.99549 |
0.99523 |
0.99434 |
0.99255 |
0.98885 |
0.98354 |
0.98042 |
0.98168 |
0.98247 |
0.98168 |
0.97833 |
GIIP |
575 |
1.80936 |
1.65349 |
1.53971 |
1.46127 |
1.40639 |
1.36101 |
1.32679 |
1.29502 |
1.26586 |
1.24042 |
1.21979 |
1.20227 |
|
|
0.03468
** |
0.08385 * |
0.14805 |
0.21075 |
0.26462 |
0.31546 |
0.35742 |
0.39896 |
0.43903 |
0.4753 |
0.50545 |
0.53145 |
GCN |
575 |
3.28662 |
3.34738 |
3.32592 |
3.28583 |
3.2224 |
3.11188 |
3.00656 |
2.90835 |
2.82195 |
2.75631 |
2.68461 |
2.62199 |
|
|
0.00000*** |
0.00000*** |
0.00000*** |
0.00000*** |
0.00000*** |
0.00000*** |
0.00000*** |
0.00000*** |
0.00001*** |
0.00001*** |
0.00003*** |
0.00006*** |
GCR |
575 |
1.2466 |
1.30352 |
1.32011 |
1.3356 |
1.34475 |
1.32818 |
1.30218 |
1.27093 |
1.24581 |
1.23116 |
1.21097 |
1.19413 |
|
|
0.46639 |
0.38762 |
0.36596 |
0.34633 |
0.33503 |
0.35566 |
0.38939 |
0.43194 |
0.46753 |
0.48876 |
0.5185 |
0.54362 |
GCP |
575 |
4.63613 |
4.15359 |
3.81082 |
3.53646 |
3.30485 |
3.10431 |
2.93944 |
2.80386 |
2.68482 |
2.57655 |
2.47743 |
2.39149 |
|
|
0.00000*** |
0.00000*** |
0.00000*** |
0.00000*** |
0.00000*** |
0.00000*** |
0.00000*** |
0.00001*** |
0.00003*** |
0.00009*** |
0.00022*** |
0.00047*** |
Note: The null hypothesis is no stochastic dependence. Probability levels given below the Lo test
statistics. Statistical significance
at the 10% level indicated by *, at the 5% level **, at the 1% level by ***. |
This section discusses and interprets the results of five alternative fractal analysis methods for measuring the Hurst exponent H presented in Table 2. All data are converted to first differences, losing one observation. Standard errors are given in parentheses. H is estimated first for monthly data over the 1959-2006 sample.
Five techniques for
estimating the
1.) Rescaled-range or R/S analysis: R/S analysis is the traditional technique introduced by Mandelbrot (1972a). Hs estimated by this method are generally far from 0.50, suggesting non-Gaussian processes. The difference between estimated Hs and 0.50 is statistically significant over the whole sample range and both subsamples for each series examined. Hs are always below 0.50, indicating ergodicity or antipersistence, e.g., negative serial correlation meaning the data processes persistently overcorrect. This measurable antipersistence or ergodicity demonstrates policy makers habitually overreact to new information, and never learn not to.
Hs different from 0.50 demonstrate the data series have not been random walks; nevertheless, this finding may be due to short-term dependence still present after taking AR1 residuals, or systematic bias due to information asymmetries, or both.
2.) Power spectral density analysis: Hs estimated by this technique also fall in the persistent range (H < 0.50). Spectral density often provides very large standard errors for H.
3.) Roughness-length relationship method: All Hs are significantly less than 0.50, indicating antipersistence.
4.) Variogram analysis: Variogram analysis supports antipersistence for all series.
5.) Wavelet analysis: This method was developed by Daubechies (1990), Beylkin (1992), and Coifman et al (1992). Wavelet H estimates indicate antipersistence or ergodicity (H < 0.50) for time deposits, the 10 year and 3 month interest rates, the index of industrial production, and the consumption price deflator. Results suggest trend-reinforcing, persistent character for all other variables, in contrast with the other techniques.
6.) Lo's (1991) modified R/S analysis: Hypothesis tests are reported in Table 3. Lo's technique does not provide an estimate for H and the null hypothesis of no stochastic dependence is necessary to lend any credence to long memory suggested by the other five methods. Strong evidence of stochastic dependence extending at least one year is found for the monetary base, M1, M2, M3, MZM, currency, checkable deposits, time deposits, nominal consumption, and the consumption deflator. The Index of Industrial Production appears to be stochastically dependent, but only with a two-month lag.
|
Table 4 Fractal Analyses of Macromonetary Quarterly Data Processes 1947-2006 Estimated Hurst Exponent H, Various Methods (Standard Errors in Parentheses) |
|||||
variable |
R/S |
Power Spectrum |
Roughness-length |
Variogram |
Wavelet |
|
GDI |
0.162 |
-0.5885 |
0.099 |
-0.032 |
0.351 |
|
|
(0.0038666) |
(4.31637) |
(0.0001122) |
(0.0258613) |
|
|
GCN |
0.087 |
-0.499 |
0.127 |
-0.036 |
0.311 |
|
|
(0.0013857) |
(15.4324) |
(0.0003282) |
(0.0789028) |
|
|
GC |
0.144 |
-0.4225 |
0.145 |
-0.003 |
0.229 |
|
|
(0.0020723) |
(3.91107) |
(0.0000446) |
(0.0504925) |
|
|
GIN |
0.066 |
-0.6565 |
0.178 |
-0.023 |
0.402 |
|
|
(0.0044745) |
(5.94697) |
(0.0000314) |
(0.0809408) |
|
|
GI |
0.078 |
-0.769 |
0.171 |
-0.018 |
0.336 |
|
|
(0.0035645) |
(7.35241) |
(0.0000105) |
(0.0726327) |
|
|
GP |
0.418 |
0.248 |
0.395 |
0.245 |
0.243 |
|
|
(0.0013298) |
(4.95443) |
(0.0018726) |
(0.0106749) |
|
|
GM1 |
0.018 |
-0.0585 |
0.188 |
0.124 |
0.504 |
|
|
(0.0139340) |
(3.96447) |
(0.0007898) |
(0.0496912) |
|
|
GM2 |
0.137 |
-0.046 |
0.304 |
0.111 |
0.104 |
|
|
(0.0093461) |
(4.71824) |
(0.0000533) |
(0.0270818) |
|
|
GMB |
0.177 |
-0.2795 |
0.206 |
0.018 |
0.083 |
|
|
(0.0052624) |
(6.16468) |
(0.0000216) |
(0.0176325) |
|
|
RP |
0.301 |
0.2655 |
0.372 |
0.225 |
0.199 |
|
|
(0.0281422) |
(3.9015610) |
(0.0011170) |
(0.1853207) |
|
|
AP1 |
0.307 |
0.2575 |
0.362 |
0.219 |
0.234 |
|
|
(0.0238342) |
(4.8460107) |
(0.0010277) |
(0.1989056) |
|
|
AP2 |
0.305 |
0.2665 |
0.383 |
0.252 |
0.328 |
|
|
(0.0199283) |
(8.0910254) |
(0.0001840) |
(0.1033507) |
|
|
APB |
0.295 |
0.249 |
0.376 |
0.211 |
0.191 |
|
|
(0.0279218) |
(4.3645687) |
(0.0011405) |
(0.2017907) |
|
|
|
Note: The
Mandelbrot-Lévy characteristic exponent alpha is the reciprocal of the |
|||||
Table 5 Lo Test for Stochastic
Dependence on Macromonetary Quarterly Data Processes 1947-2006 (Probability Levels in
Parentheses) |
||||||||
|
Autoregressive Order |
|||||||
|
1 |
2 |
3 |
4 |
5 |
6 |
7 |
8 |
GDI |
1.40673 |
1.38759 |
1.37816 |
1.41393 |
1.46503 |
1.49573 |
1.50748 |
1.52146 |
|
0.26426 |
0.285 |
0.29558 |
0.25672 |
0.20737 |
0.18118 |
0.17184 |
0.16119 |
GNC |
3.07276 |
2.72132 |
2.53354 |
2.42323 |
2.32137 |
2.2517 |
2.17212 |
2.10373 |
|
0.00000*** |
0.00002*** |
0.00013*** |
0.00036*** |
0.00086*** |
0.00152*** |
0.00285*** |
0.00478*** |
GC |
1.17211 |
1.07542 |
1.03438 |
1.02329 |
1.01993 |
1.03555 |
1.04176 |
1.06216 |
|
0.5768 |
0.72103 |
0.77803 |
0.79266 |
0.79702 |
0.77647 |
0.7681 |
0.73988 |
GNI |
0.79473 |
0.75217 |
0.74163 |
0.76791 |
0.81151 |
0.87051 |
0.93236 |
0.99374 |
|
0.98007 |
0.99053 |
0.9923 |
0.98732 |
0.97423 |
0.94429 |
0.89547 |
0.82966 |
GI |
0.79473 |
0.75217 |
0.74163 |
0.76791 |
0.81151 |
0.87051 |
0.93236 |
0.99374 |
|
0.98007 |
0.99053 |
0.9923 |
0.98732 |
0.97423 |
0.94429 |
0.89547 |
0.82966 |
GP |
4.20451 |
3.48924 |
3.05428 |
2.75439 |
2.53518 |
2.36609 |
2.23081 |
2.11905 |
|
0.00000*** |
0.00000*** |
0.00000*** |
0.00002*** |
0.00013*** |
0.00059*** |
0.00180*** |
0.00427*** |
GM1 |
3.32571 |
2.89285 |
2.60312 |
2.4221 |
2.27724 |
2.15938 |
2.07015 |
1.99938 |
|
0.00000*** |
0.00000*** |
0.00007*** |
0.00036*** |
0.00124*** |
0.00315*** |
0.00612 ** |
0.01011 ** |
GM2 |
3.46758 |
2.99392 |
2.69202 |
2.48458 |
2.32315 |
2.19482 |
2.09177 |
2.00902 |
|
0.00000*** |
0.00000*** |
0.00003*** |
0.00021*** |
0.00084*** |
0.00239*** |
0.00522 ** |
0.00945 ** |
GMB |
3.27019 |
2.8996 |
2.66144 |
2.48498 |
2.34316 |
2.23141 |
2.13708 |
2.05403 |
|
0.00000*** |
0.00000*** |
0.00004*** |
0.00021*** |
0.00071*** |
0.00179*** |
0.00373*** |
0.00687 ** |
RBCPROD |
2.7654 |
2.333 |
2.09299 |
1.94231 |
1.83737 |
1.75876 |
1.6953 |
1.64139 |
|
0.00001*** |
0.00078*** |
0.00518 ** |
0.01490 ** |
0.02923 ** |
0.04679 ** |
0.06694 * |
0.08935 * |
ABCPROD(M1) |
3.00105 |
2.52607 |
2.25997 |
2.09153 |
1.97312 |
1.88391 |
1.81197 |
1.75144 |
|
0.00000*** |
0.00014*** |
0.00142*** |
0.00523 ** |
0.01211 ** |
0.02182 ** |
0.03414 ** |
0.04881 ** |
ABCPROD(M2) |
3.44684 |
2.88252 |
2.55647 |
2.34426 |
2.19134 |
2.07343 |
1.97766 |
1.89731 |
|
0.00000*** |
0.00000*** |
0.00011*** |
0.00071*** |
0.00246*** |
0.00597 ** |
0.01174 ** |
0.02002 ** |
ABCPROD(MB) |
2.79195 |
2.35869 |
2.1195 |
1.97094 |
1.86826 |
1.79163 |
1.72937 |
1.67584 |
|
0.00001*** |
0.00063*** |
0.00425*** |
0.01229 ** |
0.02410 ** |
0.03857 ** |
0.05537 * |
0.07442 * |
Note: The null hypothesis is no stochastic dependence. Probability levels given below the Lo test
statistics. Statistical significance
at the 10% level indicated by *, at the 5% level **, at the 1% level by ***. |
Five estimates of the Hurst exponent for quarterly variables over the 1947-2006 range are presented in Table 4. R/S analysis suggests antipersistence for all series. Power spectral density functions indicate the GDP deflator, M1, and M2 are persistent, but that all other series are antipersistent, though standard errors are too high to allow much confidence in these estimates. Roughness-length and variogram estimates indicate antipersistence for all series. Wavelets suggest all series are antipersistent except M1which is either nearly normal or slightly persistent. Lo tests are reported in Table 5 with up to eight quarters of autoregressive processes removed. Results indicate stochastic persistence for nominal consumption, M1, M2, the monetary base, the GDP deflator, and for all productivity ratios, for up to eight quarters.
Conclusion
The logarithmic
differences of macroeconomic data for a stable and growing economy should have
A scenario rendering this finding more intuitive is that information relevant to a nation's macroeconomic performance arrives frequently, in infinitesimal increments, and seemingly at random. Decision makers habitually ignore the vast majority of this information, because the vast majority is unimportant or irrelevant, until it accumulates a critical mass they must finally recognize. Then, perceiving they have ignored a body of relevant information which they have allowed to accumulate, they attempt to compensate for their history of informational sloth by overreacting. The expression "informational sloth" can just as validly be characterized as "filtering out noise."
References
Andersen, Torben G.; Bollerslev, Tim. 1997. "Heterogeneous Information Arrivals and Return Volatility Dynamics: Uncovering the Long-run in High Frequency Returns." Journal of Finance, 52(3): 975-1005.
Barkoulas, John T.; Baum, Christopher F. 1996. "Long-term Dependence in Stock Returns." Economics Letters 53: 253-259.
_____; _____. 1997a. "Fractional Differencing Modeling and Forecasting of Eurocurrency Deposit Rates." Journal of Financial Research 20(3): 355-372.
_____; _____. 1997b. "Long Memory and Forecasting in Euroyen Deposit Rates." Financial Engineering and the Japanese Markets 4(3): 189-201.
_____; _____. 1997c."A Re-examination of the Fragility of Evidence from Cointegration-based Tests of Foreign Exchange Market Efficiency." Applied Financial Economics 7: 635-643.
Barkoulas, John T.; Baum, Christopher F.; Oguz, Gurkan S. 1998. "Stochastic Long Memory in Traded Goods Prices." Applied Economics Letters 5: 135-138.
Barkoulas, John T.; Labys, Walter C.; Onochie, Joseph. 1997. "Fractional Dynamics in International Commodity Prices" Journal of Futures Markets 17(2): 161-189.
Barkoulas, John T.; Travlos, Nickolaos. 1998. "Chaos in an Emerging Capital Market? The Case of the Athens Stock Exchange" Applied Financial Economics 8: 231-243.
Beylkin, Gregory. 1992. "On the Representation of Operators in Bases of Compactly Supported Wavelets." SIAM Journal on Numerical Analysis 29(6): 1716-1740.
Black, Fisher; Scholes, Myron. 1972. "The Valuation of Option Contracts and a Test of Market Efficiency." Journal of Finance 27: 399-418.
_____; _____. 1973. "The Pricing of Options and Corporate Liabilities." Journal of Political Economy 81: 637-418.
Byers, J.D.; Peel, D.A. 1996. "Long-memory Risk Premia in Exchange Rates." Manchester School of Economic and Social Studies 64(4): 421-438.
Calvet, Laurent;
Fisher, Adlai; Mandelbrot, Benoit B. 1997. "Large Deviations and the
Distribution of Price Changes," Cowles Foundation Discussion Paper no.
1165.
Cheung, Yin-Wong. 1993. "Tests for Fractional Integration: a Monte Carlo Investigation." Journal of Time Series Analysis 14: 331-345.
Cheung, Yin-Wong; Lai, Kon S. 1993. "Do Gold Market Returns Have Long Memory?" The Financial Review 28(3): 181-202.
Chou, W.L.; Shih, Y.C. 1997. "Long-run Purchasing Power Parity and Long-term Memory: Evidence from Asian Newly-industrialized Countries." Applied Economics Letters 4: 575-578.
Coifman, Ronald; Ruskai,
Mary Beth; Beylkin, Gregory; Daubechies, Ingrid; Mallat, Stephane; Meyer, Yves;
Raphael, Louise, eds. 1992. Wavelets and Their Applications.
Corazza, Marco; Malliaris, A.G.; Nardelli, Carla. 1997. "Searching for Fractal Structure in Agricultural Futures Markets." Journal of Futures Markets 71(4): 433-473.
Daubechies, Ingrid. 1990. "The Wavelet Transform, Time-frequency Localization and Signal Analysis." IEEE Transactions on Information Theory 36: 961-1005.
Diebold, Francis X.; Inoue, A. 2000. "Long Memory and Regime Switching." National Bureau of Economic Research technical working paper no. 264.
Duan, Jin-Chuan; Jacobs, Kris. 1996. "A Simple Long-memory Equilibrium Interest Rate Model." Economics Letters 53: 317-321.
Fama, Eugene; Fisher, L.; Jensen, M., and Roll, R. 1969. " The Adjustment of Stock Prices to New Information" International Economic Review 10: 1-21.
Fang, H.; Lai, Kon S.; Lai, M. 1994. "Fractal Structure in Currency Futures Prices." Journal of Futures Markets 14: 169-181.
Fisher, Adlai;
Calvet, Laurent; Mandelbrot, Benoit B. 1997. "Multifractality of Deutschemark/US
Dollar Exchange Rates." Cowles Foundation Discussion Paper no. 1166.
Gilanshah, Catherine B.; Koppl, Roger. 2005. "Big Players and Money Demand." In: Backhouse, Jürgen. (ed.) Modern Applications of Austrian Economics. New York: Routledge.
Gnedenko, Boris Vladimirovich; Kolmogorov, Andrei Nikolaevich. 1954. Limit Distributions for Sums of Random Variables. Reading, Massachusetts: Addison-Wesley.
Gordon, Robert J. 1986. The American Business Cycle: Continuity and Change. Chicago and London: University of Chicago Press.
Granger,
C.W.J. 1989. Forecasting in Business and Economics (2nd
ed.)
Granger, C.W.J.; Hyung, N. 1999. "Occasional Structural Breaks and Long Memory." Discussion paper 99-14. University of California at San Diego.
Greene, M.T.; Fielitz, B.D. 1977. "Long-term Dependence in Common Stock Returns." Journal of Financial Economics 5: 339-349.
Hays, Patrick; Schreiber, Max; Payne, James E.; Ewing, Bradley T.; Piette, Michael J. 2000. "Are Net Discount Ratios Stationary? Evidence of Mean-Reversion and Persistence." Journal of Risk and Insurance 67(3): 439-449.
Heiner, Ronald A. 1980. "The Origin of Predictable Behavior." American Economic Review 73(3): 560-595.
Hurst, H. Edwin. 1951. "Long-term Storage Capacity of Reservoirs." Transactions of the American Society of Civil Engineers 116: 770-799.
Hurst, H. Edwin; et al. 1965. Long-term Storage, an Experimental Study. London: Constable.
Jarque, C.M., and A.K. Bera (1980). "Efficient Tests for Normality, Homoskedasticity, and Serial Independence of Regression Residuals." Economics Letters 6: 255-259.
Kaen, Fred R.; Rosenman, Robert E. 1986. "Predictable Behavior in Financial Markets: Some Evidence in Support of Heiner's Hypothesis." American Economic Review 76(1): 212-220.
Kraemer, Walter; Runde, Ralf. 1997. "Chaos and the Compass Rose." Economics Letters 54: 113-118.
Koppl, Roger; Ahmed, Ehsan; Rosser, J. Barkley; White, Mark V. 1997. "Complex Bubble Persistence in Closed-End Country Funds." Journal of Economic Behavior and Organization 32(1): 19-37.
Koppl, Roger; Broussard, John. 1999. "Big Players and the Russian Ruble: Explaining Volatility Dynamics." Managerial Finance 25(1): 49-63.
Koppl, Roger; Nardone, Carlo. 2001. "The Angular Distribution of Asset Returns in Delay Space." Discrete Dynamics in Nature and Society 6: 101-120.
Koppl, Roger; Yeager, Leland, 1996. "Big Players and Herding in Asset Markets: The Case of the Russian Ruble," Explorations in Economic History, 33(3): 367-383.
Lévy, Paul. 1925. Calcul des Probibilités. Paris: Gauthier Villars.
Lo, Andrew W. 1991. "Long-term Memory in Stock Market Prices." Econometrica 59(3): 1279-1313.
Lo, Andrew W.; MacKinlay, A. 1988. "Stock Market Prices Do Not Follow a Random Walk: Evidence from a Simple Specification Test." Review of Financial Studies 1: 41-66.
_____; _____. 1989. "The Size and Power of the Variance Ratio Test in Finite Samples: a Monte Carlo Investigation." Journal of Econometrics 40: 203-238.
Malkiel,
Mandelbrot, Benoit B. 1963a. "New Methods in Statistical Economics." Journal of Political Economy 71(5): 421-440.
_____. 1963b. "The Variation of Certain Speculative Prices." Journal of Business 36(3): 394-419.
_____. 1972a. "Statistical Methodology for Non-periodic Cycles: From the Covariance to R/S Analysis." Annals of Economic and Social Measurement 1(3): 255-290.
_____. 1972b. "Possible Refinements of the Lognormal Hypothesis Concerning the Distribution of Energy Dissipation in Intermittent Turbulence." In Rosenblatt, M.; Van Atta, C. (eds.) Statistical Models and Turbulence. New York: Springer Verlag.
_____. 1974. "Intermittent Turbulence in Self Similar Cascades: Divergence of High Moments and Dimension of the Carrier." Journal of Fluid Mechanics 62: 331-358.
_____. 1975. "Limit Theorems on the Self-normalized Range for Weakly and Strongly Dependent Processes." Zeitschrift für Wahrscheinlichkeitstheorie und Verwandte Gebiete 31: 271-285.
_____. 1977. The Fractal Geometry of Nature. New York: Freeman.
Mandelbrot, Benoit B.; Fisher, Adlai; Calvet, Laurent. 1997. "A Multifractal Model of Asset Returns." Cowles Foundation Discussion Paper no. 1164. Yale University.
Mandelbrot,
Benoit B.; van
Mandelbrot, Benoit B.; Wallis, James R. 1969. "Robustness of the Rescaled Range R/S in the Measurement of Noncyclic Long-run Statistical Dependence." Water Resources Research 5(4): 976-988.
Mulligan, Robert F. 2000a. "A Fractal Analysis of Foreign Exchange Markets." International Advances in Economic Research 6(1): 33-49.
_____. 2000b. "A Characteristic Exponent Test for the Cauchy Distribution." Atlantic Economic Journal 28(4): 491.
_____. 2004. "Fractal Analysis of Highly Volatile Markets: an Application to Technology Equities." Quarterly Review of Economics and Finance. 44(1): 155-179.
Mulligan, Robert F.; Lombardo, Gary A. 2004. "Maritime Businesses: Volatile Prices and Market Valuation Inefficiencies." Quarterly Review of Economics and Finance 44(2): 321-336.
Mussa, Michael. 1984. "The Theory of Exchange Rate Determination." In Bilson, John F.O.: Marston, Richard C. (eds.) Exchange Rate Theory and Practice (pp. 13-78.) Chicago: University of Chicago Press.
Neely, Christopher; Weller, Paul; Dittmar, Robert. 1997. "Is Technical Analysis in the Foreign Exchange Market Profitable? a Genetic Programming Approach." Journal of Financial and Quantitative Analysis 32(4): 405-426.
Osborne, M. 1959. "Brownian Motions in the Stock Market." Operations Research 7: 145-173.
Peters, Edgar E. 1994. Fractal Market Analysis. New York: Wiley.
_____. 1996. Chaos and Order in the Capital Markets: a New View of Cycles, Prices, and Market Volatility (2nd ed.) New York: Wiley.
_____. 1999. Complexity, Risk, and Financial Markets. New York: Wiley.
Samuelson, Paul A. 1982. "Paul Cootner's Reconciliation of Economic Law with Chance." In Scharpe, William F.; Cootner, Cathryn M. (eds.) Financial Economics: Essays in Honor of Paul Cootner (pp. 101-117.) Englewood Cliffs, New Jersey: Scott Foresman.
Glossary of
Fractal Analysis Terms |
ARFIMA process –
autoregressive fractally integrated moving average process,
represented by ARFIMA(p,d,q), where, as with an ARIMA(p,d,q) process, p represents
the order of autoregression process, d the order of integration (i.e., the
number of times the process must be differenced to impose stationarity), and
q the order of the moving average process.
An ARFIMA process differs from ARIMA in that the order of integration
is not constrained to be an integer. |
Antipersistence – a series that reverses itself
more often than a purely random series, also called pink noise, ergodicity,
1/f noise, or negative serial correlation. (Peters 1994: 306). |
Black noise – a series that reverses itself less
often than a purely random series, displaying trends or repetitive patterns
over time, also called persistence, positive serial correlation, or
autocorrelation. (Peters 1994: 183-187). |
Brown noise – the cumulative sum of a
normally-distributed random variable, also called Brownian motion. (Peters
1994: 183-185; Osborne 1959). |
Efficient Market Hypothesis – the proposition that market prices fully and correctly reflect all relevant information. A market is described as efficient with respect to an information set if prices do not change when the information is revealed to all market participants. There are three levels of market efficiency: weak, semi-strong, and strong. (Fama et al 1969; Malkiel 1987). |
Lo test –
the statistical test of the null hypothesis of no stochastic dependence based
on computation of Qn, a modified rescaled range statistic (Lo
1991). |
Long memory – the property that any value a series takes on generally has a long and persistent effect, e.g., extreme values that repeat at fairly regular intervals. (Peters 1994: 274). |
Multifractal Model of Asset Returns (MMAR) – a very general model of asset pricing behavior allowing for long-memory and fat-tailed distributions. Instead of infinite-variance distributions such as the Mandelbrot-Lévy and Cauchy distributions, the MMAR relies on fractional combinations of random variables with non-constant mean and variance, providing many of the properties of infinite-variance distributions. (Mandelbrot, Fisher, and Calvet 1997). |
Non-periodic long cycles - a characteristic of long-memory processes, i.e., of statistical processes where each value has a long and persistent impact on values that follow it, that identifiable patterns tend to repeat over similar, though irregular, cycles (non-periodic cycles.) Also called the Joseph effect. (Peters 1994: 266). |
Non-stationarity – the property that a series has a systematically varying mean and variance. Any series with a trend, e.g., U.S. GDP, has a growing mean and therefore is non-stationary. Brown-noise processes are non-stationary, but white-noise processes are stationary. (Granger 1989: 58). |
Persistence or persistent dependence – a series that reverses itself less often than a purely random series, and thus tends to display a trend, also called black noise. Persistent series have long memory in that events are correlated over long time periods, and thus display non-periodic long cycles. (Peters 1994: 310). |
Semi-strong-form Market Efficiency – the
intermediate form of the efficient market hypothesis, asserting that market
prices incorporate all publicly available information, including both
historical data on the prices in question, and any other relevant,
publicly-available data, and thus it is impossible for any market participant
to gain advantage and earn excess profits, in the absence of inside
information. (Peters 1994: 308). |
Short-term dependence - the property that any value
a series takes on generally has a transient effect, e.g., extreme values bias
the series for a certain number of observations that follow. Eventually, however, all memory of the
extreme event is lost, in contrast to long-memory or the Joseph effect. Special cases include Markov processes and
serial correlation. (Peters 1994:
274). |
Spectral density or Power-spectral Density Analysis – a fractal analysis based on the power spectra calculated through the Fourier transform of a series. (Peters 1994: 170-171). |
Stationarity – the property that a series has a constant mean and variance. White, pink, and black-noise processes are all stationary. Because it is the cumulative sum of a white-noise process, a brown-noise process is non-stationary. (Granger 1989: 58). |
Stochastic dependence – the property that time
series exhibit non-periodic cycles.
Behavior will be persistent for an unpredictable period (the Joseph
effect) but may also be washed out, reversed, changed, or memory may be lost
by some randomly-occuring event (the Noah effect.) |
Strong-form Market Efficiency – the most restrictive version of the efficient market hypothesis, asserting that all information known to any one market participant is fully reflected in the price, and thus insider information provides no speculative advantage and cannot offer above average returns. (Malkiel 1987: 120). |
Weak-form Market Efficiency – the least restrictive version of the efficient market hypothesis, asserting that current prices fully reflect the historical sequence of past prices. One implication is that investors cannot obtain above-average returns through analyzing patterns in historical data, i.e., through technical analysis. Also referred to as the Random Walk Hypothesis. One common way of testing for weak-form efficiency is to test price series for normality, however, normality is a sufficient rather than a necessary condition. (Malkiel 1987: 120). |
White noise – a perfectly random process exhibiting no serial dependence. Normal processes meet this requirement, and normality is often conflated with white noise. Normality is a sufficient condition rather than a necessary condition for white noise. (Peters 1994: 312). |
Appendix
Statistical methodology
Lo's modified Rescaled-range: Lo (1991) developed the adjusted R/S statistic, Qn,
replacing the denominator of the R/S with the square root of the sum of the
sample variance and weighted covariance terms, and which has the property that
its statistical behavior is invariant over a general class of short memory
processes but deviates for long memory processes. Lo (1991) and Lo and
MacKinlay (1988) used this technique to find little evidence of long memory in
stock prices. Lo's Qn has the advantage that it is robust against
short-term dependence, provided Lo's underlying assumptions are satisfied.
Statistically
significant Qn's indicate rejection of the null hypothesis of no
long-term dependence or long memory. The largest lag order of
statistically significant Q-statistics gives the average non-periodic cycle
length, beyond which most long memory (memory of initial conditions) is lost.
Rescaled-range or R/S analysis: R/S analysis is the conventional method introduced by Mandelbrot (1972a). Time series are classified according to the estimated value of the Hurst exponent H, which is defined from the relationship
R/S
= anH
where R is the average range of all subsamples of size n, S is the average standard deviation for all samples of size n, a is a scaling variable, and n is the size of the subsamples, which is allowed to range from an arbitrarily small value to the largest subsample the data will allow. Putting this expression in logarithms yields
log(R/S) = log(a) + H log(n)
which is used to estimate H as a regression slope. Standard errors are given in parentheses. H ranges from 1.00 to 0.50 for persistent series, is exactly equal to 0.50 for random walks, ranges from zero to 0.50 for anti-persistent series, and is greater than one for a persistent or autocorrelated series. Mandelbrot, Fisher, and Calvet (1997) refer to H as the self-affinity index or scaling exponent.
Power spectral density analysis: This method uses the properties of power spectra of self-affine traces, calculating the power spectrum P(k) where k = 2p/l is the wavenumber, and l is the wavelength, and plotting the logarithm of P(k) versus log(k), after applying a symmetric taper function which transforms the data smoothly to zero at both ends. If the series is self-affine, this plot follows a straight line with a negative slope –b, which is estimated by regression and reported as beta, along with its standard error. This coefficient is related to the fractal dimension by: D = (5 - beta)/2. H and alpha are computed as H = 2 – D, and alpha = 1/H. Power spectral density is the most common technique used to obtain the fractal dimension in the literature, although it is also highly problematic due to spectral leakage.
Roughness-length relationship method: This method is similar to R/S, substituting the root-mean-square (RMS) roughness s(w) and window size w for the standard deviation and range. Then H is computed by regression from a logarithmic form of the relationship s(w) = wH. As noted above, the roughness-length method provides standard errors so low the null hypothesis of H = 0.500 is nearly always rejected no matter how nearly normal the asset returns.
Variogram analysis: The variogram, also known as variance of
the increments, or structure function, is defined as the expected value of the
squared difference between two y values in a series separated by a distance
w. In other words, the sample variogram
V(w) of a series y(x) is measured as:
V(w) = [y(x) – y(x+w)]2, thus V(w) is the average value of
the squared difference between pairs of points at distance w . The distance of
separation w is also referred to as the lag.
The
Wavelet analysis: Wavelet analysis exploits localized variations in power by decomposing a series into time frequency space to determine both the dominant modes of variability and how those modes vary in time. This method is appropriate for analysis of non-stationary traces such as asset prices, i.e. where the variance does not remain constant with increasing length of the data set. Fractal properties are present where the wavelet power spectrum is a power law function of frequency. The wavelet method is based on the property that wavelet transforms of the self-affine traces also have self-affine properties.
Consider n wavelet
transforms each with a different scaling coefficient ai, where S1,
S2,..., Sn are the
standard deviations from zero of the scaling coefficients ai. Then define the ratio of the standard
deviations G1, G2, ..., Gn-1 as: G1
= S1/S2, G2
= S2/S3, ..., Gn-1 = Sn-1/Sn. Then the average value of Gi is
estimated as Gavg = (Gi)/(n – 1). The estimated